دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 819
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

ریسک پیش فرض درون زا در زنجیره تامین و قیمت گذاری غیر خطی

عنوان انگلیسی
Endogenous default risk in supply chain and non-linear pricing
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
819 2012 7 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : International Journal of Production Economics, Volume 139, Issue 1, September 2012, Pages 90–96

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
ریسک پیش فرض درون زا - انتخاب بازی - زنجیره تامین - قیمت گذاری غیرخطی -
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  ریسک پیش فرض درون زا در زنجیره تامین و قیمت گذاری غیر خطی

چکیده انگلیسی

Based on incomplete contract theories, we studied the strategic behaviors of up-stream and down-stream manufacturers by option game model and obtain some conclusions. First, the down-stream's pay-off function is a concave function of its investment in fixed assets, so there is an optimal investment, which ensures the down-stream's maximal pay-off and prevents it from being holdup. Second, in presence of endogenous default risks, the up-stream can improve its pay-off level through non-linear pricing. Last, increasing business risks of the down-stream may lead to an increased price fluctuation of the up-stream, while the down-stream's technological advancement can make such fluctuation less.

مقدمه انگلیسی

From 2007 to the recent financial crisis, as down-stream manufacturers can hardly pay off goods payment or go bankrupt, numerous suppliers have been faced with financial distress or on the edge of bankruptcy, and some have claimed for bankruptcy liquidation. For example, as General Motors went bankrupt, auto parts suppliers in China, Japan, and Korea are faced financial distress. The dissemination of such crisis attracts concerns from auto parts suppliers and relative financial institutions. On the other hand, rankings of Takata, Yorozu, and Akebono Brake Industry have been lowered due to bankruptcy of General Motors. Of course, statesmen of different countries also show increased concerns for such crisis. The Chinese government formulated plans to revitalize the auto industry, and Toshihiro Nikai, minister of Economy, Trade and Industry of Japan, openly announced that the Japanese government would assist Japanese companies, which have been influenced by the bankruptcy of General Motors. The occurrence of such events forces us to rethink about endogenous default risks of supply chain contract as well as manufacturers' corresponding strategies. In recent years, supply chain risk management has received concerns from the academics. On the part of buyers, supply chain risks mainly include supply management, production management, information management, and demand management (Tang, 2006). From the perspective of the supply chain structure, suppliers are closely connected with down-stream manufacturers in risk. If the supplier is risky to be bankrupt, the supply price in contract may change due to the effect of bankruptcy (Babich et al., 2007). Likely, demand fluctuation of the down-stream manufacturer may convey to up-stream manufacturer (Lee et al., 1997). From the perspective of financial risk, if the down-stream manufacturer is faced with liquidity risks, the supplier can reduce the down-stream manufacturer's risk level through contract design, and the contracted price is determined by the down-stream manufacturer' market risks and decision making behaviors (Agrawal and Seshadri, 2000, Chen and Seshadri, 2006 and Wang and Webster, 2007). In addition, the supply chain may be broken by bankruptcy of the supplier or the down-stream manufacturer, leading to inefficient investment and moral hazard (Bakshi and Kleindorfer, 2009). On the other hand, according to fundamentals of accounting, a supplier's goods payment is expressed as the manufacturer's debt. Once the manufacturer cannot pay off its debt, it will go bankrupt, causing losses to suppliers. However, such risk factor was neglected in Christopher's framework. It follows from the recent financial crisis that such risk factor has brought fatal dangers to suppliers, one of the future difficulties the supply chain restructuring has to overcome. For this reason, we attempt to study this issue from the perspective of endogenous default risk in the supply chain contract. Endogenous default risk means that once a supply chain contract is signed, the supplier becomes a debtor of the manufacturer, who may select a bankruptcy value level endogenous in the supply chain contract under some circumstance, meaning that it will choose to go bankrupt rather than pay off goods payment once its assets add up to the selected value level. Such perspective helps to understand the manufacturer's bankruptcy behaviors as well as the ensuing restructuring. Whenever a supply-demand contract is mentioned, the problem of incomplete contract and holdup (Grossman and Hart, 1986 and Hart and Moore, 1990) is always involved. Hart and Moore (1988) analyzed reasons for holdup. Suppose a supplier signs a supply chain contract with a down-stream manufacturer and the investment level is determined by the down-stream manufacturer after the contract is signed, then the down-stream manufacturer's investment level would maximize its own pay-off rather than maximize both parties' pay-offs. The reason is that the up-stream manufacturer's default will result in sunk costs if its investment is up to such a level that both parties' pay-offs can be maximized. This example shows that there are problems of insufficient investment and holdup in a supply chain, a phenomenon studied by Böckem and Schiller (2008) with option contract. If we analyze the behaviors of up-stream and down-stream manufacturers in a supply chain contract from the perspective of incomplete contract, their pay-off function may be defined as a call option (Maskin and Tirole, 1999). This provides a basis on which to study the supply chain contract with a real option model. Currently, the real option method has been used in studying the supply chain contract. Burnetas and Ritchken (2005) argue that introduction of the option contract into the supply chain contract results in an increase in wholesale price and a decline in retail price fluctuation. Wang and Tsao (2006) provide a purchaser's optimal strategy, and Li et al. (2009) expound the role of the option contract under the condition of asymmetric information. Enlightened by such studies, we will consider optimal strategies of the contracting parties with the game theory method during our study of the supply chain contract. Based on Maskin and Tirole (1999), we suppose the up-stream manufacturer holds a call option concerned with the supply contract. Then, using the method of Black and Cox (1976), we will obtain the call option price, i.e., the pay-off function of the up-stream manufacturer. Finally, based on findings of Leland, 1994 and Leland, 1998, we will calculate the pay-off function of the down-stream manufacturer under the condition of bankruptcy. After we draw the pay-off functions of the up-stream and down-stream manufacturers, we will obtain the solution to the optimal investment strategy of the down-stream manufacturer, suggesting that the down-stream manufacturer invests insufficiently to avoid being holdup. According to Maskin and Tirole (1999), vertical integration can help to reduce the loss of welfare under this condition, but our conclusion means that market pricing mechanism can achieve a similar effect. In accordance with the terms of economics, we obtain the conclusion means that we introduced the mechanism design into the supply chain (Chen et al., 2005) and use non-linear pricing mechanism (Wilson, 1995 and Kuhn, 1997) to decrease the supply chain risk. And then, we study the non-linear pricing how to influence assets investment and technological of upstream manufacturer, the conclusion means that the up-stream manufacturer's pricing is correlated positively to the down-stream manufacturer's assets value but negatively to its technological level, which suggests that technological advancement helps to reduce price fluctuation while an increase in business risks may make price fluctuation fiercer. On the other hand, our model is similar to a zero-sum game option model, which is different from the Smit–Trigeorgis framework (Smit and Trigeorgis, 2004). In our model, down-stream manufacturer can choose optimal level of investment assets, when he go bankrupt the up-stream manufacturer will obtain all the assets, which is endogenous in our model. And when the up-stream manufacturer anticipates the down-stream manufacturer's investment behaviors, it will make pricing decisions according to the order quantity from the down-stream manufacturer, which is non-linear pricing mechanism. From the point of Game Theory, endogenous default risk and non-linear pricing is rational choice of two players. The rest of this paper is arranged as follows. Section 2 proposes a real option model of the supply contract, Section 3 focuses on nonlinear pricing, Section 4 conducts a numeric simulation of the main conclusions, and the last section is the conclusion of our paper.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

We have studied the strategic behaviors of up-stream and down-stream manufacturers through an option game model, and arrived at some enlightening conclusions. We have supposed that the down-stream manufacturer determine its investment level after the supply chain contract is signed between the up-stream and down-stream manufacturer. According to the conclusion of Maskin and Tirole (1999), the pay-off function of the up-stream manufacturer can be viewed as a call option. Our findings show that if the investment level of the down-stream manufacturer is above some critical value View the MathML sourceVB∘, it is positively correlated the pay-off of the up-stream manufacturer. However, the investment level View the MathML sourceVB⁎ which can maximize the pay-off of the down-stream manufacturer is less than View the MathML sourceVB∘, meaning that there is some optimal investment level which can both maximize the pay-off of the down-stream manufacturer and prevent the down-stream manufacturer from being holdup. Meanwhile, after the up-stream manufacturer has anticipated the down-stream manufacturer's investment behaviors, it will make pricing decisions according to the order quantity from the down-stream manufacturer. Our findings demonstrate that there is an optimal nonlinear pricing strategy, and the up-stream manufacturer's pricing is correlated positively to the down-stream manufacturer's assets value but negatively to its technological level, suggesting that technological advancement helps to reduce price fluctuation while an increase in business risks may make price fluctuation fiercer. We have not taken into consideration the ex-post-re-negotiation problem, but it does not mean that re-negotiation is not important but that it is unrelated to our hypotheses. Suppose the down-stream manufacturer decides to choose between highly risky and less risky investment projects after it continues to operate in another period of time, it will demand adding selective items including re-negotiation in the contract. This means that the down-stream manufacturer will choose different pricing strategies before or after the risk is transferred. Risk transfer, also termed regime model in mathematics (Guo and Zhang, 2004), has attracted increased concerns in recent years. Of course, the related supply chain contract design is worthy of further study.