دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 24273
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

یک نظریه کمی از امنیت اجتماعی بدون تعهد

عنوان انگلیسی
A quantitative theory of social security without commitment
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
24273 2008 20 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Journal of Public Economics, Volume 92, Issues 3–4, April 2008, Pages 652–671

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
سیاست های مارکوف - پیری جمعیت - امنیت اجتماعی -
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
,Markov policies,Population ageing,Social security,
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  یک نظریه کمی از امنیت اجتماعی بدون تعهد

چکیده انگلیسی

This paper investigates the determination of social security within a general equilibrium, overlapping-generations model where agents live for many periods, and replacement rates are determined through voting in each period by forward looking agents. The distinctive feature is the study of Markov equilibrium policy outcomes which do not rest on a commitment mechanism. Versions of the model are calibrated to the US economic, policy, and demographic conditions. Even in the absence of commitment, the policy preferences of tax-paying working-age voters sustain a positive level of retirement benefits. This follows because the current choices about social security will have, at the time when the current voters will retire, a positive impact on the political support for social security and on the returns to savings. On the other hand, the projected decline in the U.S. population growth rate causes the replacement rate and the tax rate to decline. This quantitative response without commitment differs from that in the case when policies are committed at time zero.

مقدمه انگلیسی

Unfunded social security systems can be found in virtually all major developed economies. The size of social security remains large, with estimated average replacement rates near 40% in the U.S., and well in excess of 70% in some European countries. The anticipated demographic ageing in the U.S. and, specially, in Europe questions the viability of these pension schemes though.1 This paper's main objective is to further our understanding into why unfunded social security exists. Since the political support for public pensions can shift at any time, a challenge is to explain why they are sustained by voters who are too young to directly reap their benefits. Most literature has evaded this question by building on some form of commitment or reputation mechanism so that young voters are in effect voting on their own future pensions. In contrast, the present paper tackles the question head on by focusing on the plausibly realistic situation where political decisions on pensions are made periodically and unrestricted by past commitments. Therefore young voters today understand that their pensions will be determined in future elections. Social security transfers are self-enforced and, in this sense, arise and be maintained naturally.2 A second objective is to begin exploring how changes in the age structure of the population will influence the social security system. I will study the quantitative implications of a fall in the population growth rate, with and without commitment. The analysis is based on the properties of the preferences over policies held by voters in different age groups. These policy preferences will be characterised within the framework of a general equilibrium overlapping-generations model where agents live for many periods. More specifically, the economy is represented by the standard neoclassical model of capital accumulation, with households who make rational decisions on savings and labour supply, and a government that implements fiscal policy. There is a pay-as-you-go social security system which is funded by a flat tax rate on labour income. The system's benefits and the labour tax reflect the aggregation of these tax preferences through a political process. This investigation will focus on a majority voting setting for this process whereby the preferences of a specific age group dictate the policy choices. One distinctive characteristic of this paper is that the Markov politico-economic equilibrium introduced by Krusell et al. (1997) is adapted to study social security. Hence households vote sequentially over time taking into account the consequences of current policy choices for future policy choices, given the current state of the economy and policies. For comparison purposes, I also study the alternative assumption made in existing literature that there is a commitment (or reputation) mechanism in place and voters behave as though voting effectively takes place once and for all at time zero. Economic and fiscal policy outcomes are determined endogenously as a fixed point of the equilibrium mapping for a linear-quadratic approximation of the economy. Attention is restricted to steady-state equilibria. The model is first calibrated with exogenous social security policies to U.S. observations on values of economic variables, the average social security replacement rate, and the population growth rate. On this numerical benchmark, two main exercises are conducted. The first and central exercise seeks calibrating the model to match endogenous policy outcomes under the assumption of sequential voting without commitment. The second exercise analyses, on the calibrated setup, the effects on social security of a shift in the population growth rate consistent with predicted trends for the US over the coming decades. For comparison purposes, these experiments are also carried out under the assumption of time-zero voting with commitment. The main finding is that positive social security pensions can emerge in an efficient economy even in the absence of any form of commitment to future pensions. More specifically, with a young politically decisive group, voting without commitment can match a realistic level of social security. This is true although the pivotal agent does not reap direct gains from the pension benefits she supports. The explanation is that the current social security transfers will have a positive influence on future social security benefits and the returns to savings. The effect on the rate of return is standard and follows from the negative consequences of the transfers system on aggregate savings (i.e., the crowding out effect). The effect on future policies is less standard and has two sources. The first is that today's political support to a rise in social security taxes increases the savings of the young generations who will consequently be left with a higher level of assets in the future when they will become the middle aged influential voter. At that time, it will be in their interest to sustain social security as a way to bolster the return to capital in their retirement age. The second source is that the fall in aggregate capital that today's social security brings about will reduce the wage rate and thus the direct cost of social-security taxation for the future working-age voters. Each of these two channels renders the idea that voting is strategic in a dynamic sense: You vote today so as to influence future voter's choices. Naturally, there is no room for this type of mechanism when there is commitment to future policies.3 Regarding the other issue dealt with in this paper, the predicted reduction in population growth affects the size of social security. There is a negative general equilibrium macroeconomic effect as it bears on factor prices and the perceived costs and benefits to the transfers system. The lower population growth causes social security to decline. The quantitative response appears to be somehow sharper under the non-commitment assumption distinctive of the present paper than under the commitment case characteristic of previous works. Nonetheless, this outcome must be interpreted with some caution since the two situations may not be directly comparable. The main contribution of this paper is the analysis of social security without commitment in a general equilibrium model with fully rational agents and a considerably rich demographic structure. A body of quantitative research, in common with the present paper, also analyses quantitatively the determination of social security policies in general equilibrium. Cooley and Soares, 1996, Cooley and Soares, 1999a and Cooley and Soares, 1999b and Galasso (1999) can be counted among these papers. They analyse the political support for types of social security reform but they rely on a form of commitment (or reputation) for social security to be sustained at all in the first place.4 As such, these works restrict the scope of the strategic dynamic factors that shape policy choices. In the present paper I will focus instead on the determination of Markov policies without any form of commitment or reputation. The work pioneered by Krusell et al. (1997) – which includes Krusell and Ríos-Rull, 1999 and Krusell and Ríos-Rull, 2003, and Klein and Ríos-Rull (2003) – introduces and develops the Markov politico-economic equilibrium notion I draw upon. These papers do not consider demographic factors or social security. The present paper is closest to Mateos-Planas (2006) where that approach is extended to study demographic factors in quantitative overlapping-generations models although, unlike the present paper, the issue at hand is factor taxation.5 A few papers have studied theoretically social security as a Markov equilibrium in models with two-period lifetimes. The seminal work in Esteban and Sakovics (1993) deals with an endowment economy.6 More recently, Forni (2005) and González-Eiras and Niepelt (2005) have considered social security with capital accumulation and a neoclassical production technology. Whereas these papers study models with two lifetime periods, the present paper develops a setting with a large number of lifetime periods and a richer life cycle. This makes it more apt for the type of quantitative statements attempted here.7 The present paper does spell out the reasons for social security by analysing for the first time the off-equilibrium dynamic responses to policy deviations. The rest of the paper is organised as follows. Section 2 presents the model and then Section 3 defines and discusses the equilibrium concepts entertained in the paper. Section 4 calibrates the benchmark version of the model, and explores the different implications of sequential and time-zero voting. Section 5 analyses the dynamic mechanisms behind social security without commitment. Section 6 studies the consequences of the demographic shift. Section 7 concludes the paper. An appendix contains details on the computational method and numerical outcomes.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

This paper has studied quantitatively the determination of unfunded social security. In contrast to previous work, it uses an approach where policy decisions are sequential instead of committed at time zero. Although there is no commitment, positive social security retirement pensions arise in equilibrium. The middle age voters lend support to social security as a way to build in turn a political demand for retirement transfers in the future as well as a higher rate of return on savings. The dynamic connections between the economy and policies are key to this result. Social security today will cause a higher future interest rate through its standard negative impact on capital supply. In turn, social security will be sustained since it makes the future politically influential middle age group asset-richer and therefore more inclined to raise the rate of return to capital. An additional reason is that the corresponding lower wage makes the system's labour taxation less costly for the working-age voter. Whether voting is sequential or time-zero matters for the size of social security transfers. The non-commitment sequential approach gives rise to smaller replacement rates than the commitment time-zero approach. On the other hand, a realistic reduction in population growth brings about a downsizing of social security in either case, but the shift is more marked under non-commitment sequential voting. These findings might suggest that the assumption of commitment typical of much previous work might tend to underestimate the negative impact of ageing on the survival of unfunded social security. It may be too early too draw strong practical conclusions in this respect though. The limitations of this paper include the following. First, the framework of analysis has a deliberately sparse demographic and political structure. Second, policies other than social security are fixed. Third, transitional dynamics have not been dealt with here but are of paramount practical importance for social security reforms. Further research will pursue these issues.