دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 26341
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

استفاده از پیش بینی های خصوصی به منظور برآورد اثرات سیاست پولی

عنوان انگلیسی
Using private forecasts to estimate the effects of monetary policy
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
26341 2008 19 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Journal of Monetary Economics, Volume 55, Issue 4, May 2008, Pages 806–824

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
سیاست های پولی - پاسخ ضربه - پیش بینی -
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Monetary policy, Impulse response, Forecasts,
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  استفاده از پیش بینی های خصوصی به منظور برآورد اثرات سیاست پولی

چکیده انگلیسی

I develop a methodology that uses the forecasts of market participants and of policy makers to estimate the effects of monetary policy on output and inflation. My approach has advantages over the standard practice of fitting a vector autoregression to the data. I apply my methodology to data on output, interest rates and prices. I find that, even using the Federal Reserve Board's Greenbook forecasts to control for the policy maker's information set, prices rise initially in response to a monetary contraction. This finding undermines the standard justification for including an index of commodity prices in VARs.

مقدمه انگلیسی

Questions concerning the effect of monetary policy on output and inflation lie at the heart of macroeconomics. The key step in any analysis of the monetary transmission mechanism is the identification of exogenous shocks to monetary policy. In this paper, I use the forecasts of market participants to estimate the effects of monetary policy on output and inflation. Current practice involves fitting a linear model, called a vector autoregression or VAR, to the data and identifying monetary shocks off of the model's forecast errors. Sims (1980) introduced VARs to empirical macroeconomics. At the time, he was troubled by the “incredible” identification assumptions made by large scale macroeconomic models. In their place, he proposed regressing each of a set of variables on its own lags and lags of the other variables. The main advantage of this approach was that it could capture very complex patterns in the data with only minimal identifying assumptions. A large empirical literature has developed using VARs to analyze the effects of monetary policy on output and prices.1 In addition, many authors use VARs to motivate and evaluate their theoretical models.2 Recently, the appropriateness of the VAR methodology has come into question. The most common criticisms are its time-invariant linear structure, the low correlation between the forecasts generated by the VAR and those generated by private markets, and, in the absence of appropriate conditioning information, the occurrence of a “price puzzle”—the tendency for the price level to increase following a monetary contraction. This paper makes two contributions. First, I develop a methodology that uses market forecasts and policy maker forecasts to estimate the effects of monetary policy on output and the price level. With this methodology I am able to control for the information set of policy makers in a more direct manner than is possible with a simple linear VAR. Second, I use this methodology to estimate the effects of monetary policy on output and prices at various horizons. My results shed light on the “price puzzle.” I conclude that the price puzzle cannot be explained by the possible exclusion of information available to the policy marker. My methodology is best understood in comparison with the standard practice in the VAR literature. VAR analysis involves three steps: first, fit a linear model to data on variables of interest, such as output, interest rates and prices, and generate a set of reduced-form errors; second, identify the structural disturbances to the variables from the reduced-form errors; and third, use the estimated model to analyze the effect that these disturbances have on the endogenous variables. This last step implicitly involves regressing the reduced-form errors at various horizons on the structural disturbances. The main role that the VAR plays in this analysis is to generate the forecasts that give rise to the reduced-form errors employed in steps one and three. I use market-based expectations and the expectations of policy makers in place of the VAR forecasts at these points. The advantage of my methodology is that market-based forecasts and policy maker forecasts provide the conditional expectation of the variables of interest based on all information currently available. The VAR, however, only provides the best linear forecast based on the subset of variables that are included in the VAR system. For VAR researchers this raises the delicate issue of what variables to include in the system.3 The “price puzzle” is a classic example of the difficulties involved in this choice. In VARs with a small number of variables there is a tendency for the price level to increase following a monetary contraction. Many researchers find this result difficult to accept. They argue instead that there must exist some variable not included in the VAR that causes inflation and that the Federal Reserve is responding to information correlated with that variable. Their “solution” is to include an index of commodity prices in the VAR.4 When this is done the price puzzle disappears. This raises the question, however, of how one knows when the correct specification has been reached. To some the thought process used to justify the inclusion of commodity prices seems circular. Cochrane (1994) states that, “empirical researchers typically fish for VAR specifications to produce impulse-responses that capture qualitative monetary dynamics, for example as described in Friedman (1968).” By using market-based forecasts and policy-maker forecasts, I am better able to control for private information without explicitly including more variables in the estimation. I use my methodology to estimate the effects of monetary policy on output and prices. I use futures market data and Greenbook (GB) forecasts in place of the VAR forecasts.5 I compare the estimates obtained by using my methodology to the estimates obtained by using a VAR. I have two main results. First, my methodology predicts a stronger effect of monetary policy on output than does the VAR. Second, my methodology predicts that prices rise in response to monetary contractions. This means that the price puzzle remains even after conditioning on the information sets of policy makers. One cannot therefore rationalize the price puzzle by the exclusion of relevant information available to the policy maker.6 This undermines the standard justification given for including commodity prices in the VAR. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 begins with a brief description of the VAR estimation strategy. It describes my methodology using data on market expectations. Section 3 contains the empirical application. It introduces the data, presents the results, and discusses their robustness. Section 4 concludes.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

In this paper I develop a methodology that uses market forecasts and policy maker forecasts to estimate the effects of monetary policy on output and the price level. With this methodology I am able to control for the information set of policy makers in a more direct manner than is possible with a simple VAR. I use this methodology to shed light on the “price puzzle.” I conclude that the price puzzle cannot be explained by the possible exclusion of information available to the policy marker. Recent work by Bernanke et al. (2005) and Romer and Romer (2004) suggests that the price puzzle might be caused by missing information. However, both these studies find that the price puzzle exists over short horizons. Neither study can reject the price puzzle over horizons less than two years. In both cases impulse responses exhibit a price puzzle over short horizons. My results are consistent with their findings. By casting doubt on the omitted information theory, my methodology provides indirect evidence in favor of alternative theories for the price puzzle. One possibility is the cost channel of monetary transmission as emphasized by Barth and Ramey (2001). Another possibility is that passive policy may imply that prices rise in response to a monetary contraction as in Lubik and Schorfheide (2004) and Davig et al. (2004). It is also possible that the recursive identification assumption implies interest rate innovations that are not capturing the exogenous shocks to monetary policy. Currently the main constraint on my methodology arises from the limited availability of market-based expectations data. Some futures’ markets, such as those for GDP and inflation, are just in their infancy. This constrains the sample period over which my methodology can be applied to these variables. Others, such as those for interest rates, provide forecasts only at short horizons. This limits my ability to construct impulse response functions. In the case of interest rates, this makes it difficult to estimate the effect of monetary policy on the term structure of interest rates or to analyze the liquidity puzzle. As these markets expand their coverage, my methodology should provide an attractive alternative to VARs. There are other advantages of my methodology that I am exploiting in current work. In particular, I am using my methodology to investigate non-linearities in the response of output and prices to monetary disturbances. I am also investigating how the effects of monetary shocks depend on the monetary policy regime: whether exchange rates are fixed or flexible, or whether the central bank practices inflation targeting.