دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 26523
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

سیاست پولی بهینه و رشد اقتصادی

عنوان انگلیسی
Optimal monetary policy and economic growth
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
26523 2009 12 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : European Economic Review, Volume 53, Issue 2, February 2009, Pages 210–221

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
قانون فریدمن - اثر توبین - سیاست های پولی -
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Friedman rule, Tobin effect, Monetary policy,
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  سیاست پولی بهینه و رشد اقتصادی

چکیده انگلیسی

A question at the center of many analyses of optimal monetary policy is, why do central banks never implement the Friedman rule? To the list of answers to this question, we add neoclassical production (specifically, the Tobin effect) as one possible explanation. To that end, we study an overlapping generations economy with capital where limited communication and stochastic relocation create an endogenous transactions role for fiat money. We assume a production function with a knowledge externality (Romer style) that nests economies with endogenous growth (AK form) and those with no long-run growth (the Diamond model). The Tobin effect is shown to be always operative. Under CRRA preferences, a mild degree of social increasing returns is sufficient (but not necessary) for some positive inflation to dominate zero inflation and for the Friedman rule to be sub-optimal, irrespective of the degree of risk aversion.

مقدمه انگلیسی

The Friedman rule, Milton Friedman's classic prescription for the optimal conduct of monetary policy, remains to date the most significant dictum in monetary theory. Friedman (1969) argued that good monetary policy is one that equates the private opportunity cost of holding money (the nominal interest rate) to its social opportunity cost (which is zero). By this logic, optimal monetary policy should never be expansionary. Critics were quick to point out potential problems with this line of thinking. Phelps (1973) argued that following a contractionary policy as proposed by Friedman may require the government to make up the lost seigniorage using distortionary means which may negate the alleged benefit of the policy. Symmetrically, others have argued that seigniorage may have enough beneficial uses to justify an expansionary policy.1 Lastly, the empirical evidence suggests that central banks (CBs) never implement the Friedman rule. Walsh (2003a) identifies six countries that have targeted the inflation rate. Each has set its long-run target between zero and three percent, which is clearly inconsistent with a zero nominal interest rate. This paper studies another potential limitation of Friedman's logic using an argument first articulated in Tobin (1965): What if monetary expansion caused income to rise and grow, thereby overwhelming the non-distortionary benefit of following a contractionary policy? In today's parlance, if the Tobin effect is operative, can the Friedman rule ever be optimal? In a sense, the Tobin effect and the Friedman rule represent two divergent views on the desirability of inflation.2 The former argues that inflation, by raising the relative return to capital, stimulates capital formation and hence growth. The latter argues that monetary expansion raises the opportunity cost of holding real balances and makes liquidity, potentially a desirable commodity, more costly. Which effect dominates? More broadly, can the Tobin effect account for why we do not observe the Friedman rule being implemented.3 We address this question within the context of a monetary growth model. We specify an overlapping generations model economy with capital where limited communication and stochastic relocation create an endogenous transactions role for fiat money.4 At the end of each period, a fraction of agents is relocated; only fiat money is useful as a means to “communicate” with their past (hence the “limited communication”). The “stochastic relocations” act like shocks to agents’ portfolio preferences and, in particular, trigger liquidations of some assets at potential losses. They have the same consequences as “liquidity preference shocks” in Diamond and Dybvig (1983), and motivate a role for banks that take deposits, hold cash reserves. The other asset is a commonly available neoclassical technology with knowledge externalities, as in Romer (1986); more specifically, the production function is given by View the MathML sourceYt=AK¯tβKtθLt1-θ, where KtKt denotes the capital stock of a representative firm, LtLt denotes the amount of labor hired, and View the MathML sourceK¯t is the aggregate capital stock in the economy. The assumed knowledge-externality form of the production function nests economies with endogenous growth (AK form, i.e., θ+β=1θ+β=1) and those with no long-run growth (i.e., θ+β<1θ+β<1 as in the classic Diamond, 1965 model). Our results are as follows. Because seigniorage is rebated to young agents as a lump-sum transfer, the Tobin effect is operative. Under logarithmic utility, we show that the Friedman rule is not optimal (stationary welfare maximizing) if the steady state is dynamically efficient. In this case, we can also show that zero inflation is not optimal (indeed some amount of positive inflation dominates zero inflation). Under the more general CRRA form of preferences, we find that a sufficient (not necessary) condition for some positive inflation to dominate zero inflation is that View the MathML sourceθ+β∈(12,1); for most realistic values of θθ, this translates into a requirement that the societal production function exhibits mild increasing returns. For parameter values such that the economy is dynamically efficient under logarithmic utility, the Friedman rule is not optimal for any value of the risk aversion parameter. These results stand in contrast to those obtained in economies with linear (fixed real return) storage technologies. Since almost all the literature thus far has focused on linear storage economies and not on neoclassical production economies, an important contribution of this paper is to highlight the fact that optimal monetary policy is strikingly different in these two kinds of economies. As discussed in Wallace (1980), a linear storage economy is one in which 1 unit invested in date-t storage (or capital) returns x>1x>1 units of date-t+1t+1 units of the consumption good. By definition, such economies are dynamically efficient. Bhattacharya et al. (2005b) and others have demonstrated that linear storage random relocation economies, irrespective of the degree of risk aversion, always return a verdict in favor of zero inflation. Here, in contrast we are able to show, for example, that for logarithmic utility, zero inflation is suboptimal if the economy is dynamically efficient. The reason is that in economies with linear storage technologies, storage holdings of the current generation do not influence the incomes of future generations. With neoclassical production, instead, any seigniorage collected is rebated to the young which augments the deposit base of the young and, in standard cases, raises the investment in capital, and hence future incomes. This paper is related to a vast literature on the Friedman rule (see Bhattacharya et al., 2005a and the references therein). More specifically, our paper complements the work by Paal and Smith (2004) who study suboptimality of the Friedman rule in an environment with endogenous growth that shares many similarities with ours. In a money-in-the-utility-function overlapping generations economy with production, Weiss (1980) finds that the optimal policy produces positive inflation. Smith (1998) studies an overlapping generations monetary economy with production in which the rate of return dominance issue is settled by postulating a minimum size to capital investment that limits one group of agents to holding money. By focusing on the dynamically inefficient equilibria, he shows that welfare at the Friedman rule may be dominated by other feasible monetary policies. Similarly, Palivos (2005) studies an overlapping generations economy with production and heterogeneity in preference for altruism and finds that a case for positive inflation can be made even when capital does not respond to inflation. Our work also complements that of Dutta and Kapur (1998) who pose the exact question as ours in a overlapping generations economy with irreversible unobservable capital investments and uninsured liquidity preference risk (similar to ours). They find that the optimal inflation rate is positive if the Tobin effect is not operative. The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows: Section 2 presents the environment, the set of primitives, the spatial and informational constraints generating limited communication and the behavior of banks. Section 3 describes the general equilibrium while Section 4 discusses optimal monetary policy under different assumptions about θ+βθ+β. The final section includes some concluding remarks and the appendices contain proofs of all the major results.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

Most of the literature interested in optimal monetary policy in random relocation models has studied models with a storage technology. In this paper, we show that optimal monetary policy looks very different across random relocation models with concave production functions and those with linear storage technologies. Many authors have demonstrated that dynamically efficient linear storage random relocation economies, irrespective of the degree of risk aversion, always support zero inflation as the golden rule. Here in contrast we show, for example, that for logarithmic utility, zero inflation is never optimal if the economy is dynamically efficient. The reason for this difference lies in the power of the Tobin effect. In economies with linear storage technologies, storage holdings of the current generation do not influence the incomes of future generations. In contrast, with neoclassical production, any seigniorage collected is rebated to the young which augments the deposit base of the young, and in standard cases, raises the investment in capital (the Tobin effect) and hence future incomes. A question that is at the heart of many analyses of optimal monetary policy is, why do central banks in the real world never implement the Friedman rule? To the list of answers to this question, we add neoclassical production (specifically, the Tobin effect) as one possible explanation.