دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 23739
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

بحران ERM با نگاهی به گذشته : اگر بانک مرکزی اروپا قبل از سال 1992 وجود داشت؟

عنوان انگلیسی
ERM crisis in retrospect : What if a European central bank had been in existence before 1992?
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
23739 2011 10 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Economic Modelling, Volume 28, Issue 4, July 2011, Pages 1526–1535

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
مخالف - سیستم پولی اروپا - بحران ارز -
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Counterfactual analysis, European Monetary System, Currency crisis,
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  بحران ERM با نگاهی به گذشته : اگر بانک مرکزی اروپا قبل از سال 1992 وجود داشت؟

چکیده انگلیسی

This paper explores whether policy coordination or a single monetary policy implemented earlier would have kept the U.K. in the process of European monetary integration. On the basis of the pre-ERM crisis empirics by Douven and Plasmans (1996), a counterfactual game simulation approach is used, and five scenarios are established for comparison with the actual historical records. The final answer is negative.

مقدمه انگلیسی

Every crisis has its context (Eichengreen, 2000). But history shows that governments usually reconsider their views on international macroeconomic cooperation in the aftermath of a crisis. The year of the subprime crisis (2007) marks the 10th anniversary of the Asian financial crisis of 1997–98, and politicians are still looking for international policy coordination in the G20 summit in the face of the world financial crisis.1 Though it may go unnoticed, 2007 is also the 15th anniversary of the European Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM) crisis back in 1992–93. Is there any similarity between the current and the past financial chaos? Can we still learn anything from the coordination failure of 15 years ago? The collapse of the Bretton Woods System in 1971–3 and the resulting volatility in financial markets heightened the urgency of efforts to create a zone of monetary stability. The success of the European Monetary System (EMS), a multilateral parity with the ERM and European Currency Unit (ECU), surprised even the optimists. However, the Single Market Agreement that came in 1986 removed the controls on cross-border capital flows. With such, realigning became problematic over the subsequent five years. Where there had been 11 realignments between the birth of the EMS and January 1987, there were none from that point to the crisis in September 1992.2 Three causes triggered the crisis. The first was the German unification in 1991 and the ensuing large financing needs of the German authorities. Then came the recession that hit Europe at almost the same time. These shocks led to major conflicts about the stance of monetary policy to be pursued in the system. Finally, the lack of credibility of the Maastricht convergence criteria with the collapse of the EMS had resurrected in Europe the specter of monetary instability and beggar-my-neighbor devaluations (De Grauwe, 1994). The academia has made two responses to the crisis. The first is the well-known second-generation model (e.g., Obstfeld, 1996). It points out that speculative attacks precipitate the change in policies, which validates the expectations of the exhaustion of reserves. The second emphasizes the role of policy coordination failure from the political (e.g., Sevilla, 1995) or economic perspectives. In fact, the same warning had been presented in the Delors Report. Regardless of the complex problem of sovereignty, the relationship between policy coordination and welfare-improving is presumed to be the case in the absence of information asymmetries and strategic behavior (Wyplosz, 2006). For instance, Buiter et al. (1998) argue that a system of collective pegs, cooperatively managed, should be more stable than a unilateral peg, and that Europe's tragedy arose because it squandered its opportunity to cooperate. The failure to cooperate was what transformed market pressures into a crisis; had cooperative policies been pursued, adjustment would have been smoother and the threat to the EMS would have been less. Wyplosz (2004) argues that in theory the EMS provided automatic and unlimited support of bilateral pegs. The lira and sterling were forced to withdraw from the ERM because the Bundesbank declined to provide unlimited support to Italy and the U.K. De Grauwe (1997) indicates that it is useful to ask the question what would have happened if a European central bank had been in existence during the recession of 1992–93. He believes that a more expansionary monetary policy would have been implemented in Europe than the one that was applied in the EMS. Another issue is the implication of the ERM crisis to the prospects of monetary coordinative mechanisms in the rest of the world. In the aftermath of the Asian financial crises in 1997–98, there have been a number of initiatives to enhance monetary cooperation in the region including options for a common exchange rate system. Wilson (2006) argues that the ERM might be politically the most appealing for East Asia if the arrangements are flexible enough to leave countries initially with sufficient independence in macroeconomic policy. However, Giavazzi and Giovannini, 1988, Eichengreen, 2000 and Wyplosz, 2004 reject the possibility of the ERM being copied outside Europe. Giavazzi and Giovannini (1988) argue that the EMS has de facto worked as a Deutsche mark zone, which indicates that the fixed exchange rate arrangements per se cannot induce international monetary cooperation. Wyplosz (2004) argues that the Chiang Mai Initiative (CMI) is similar to the EMS, but the amounts to be swapped within the CMI are limited, and hence unlikely to be commensurate with the amounts that markets can mobilize. To verify the above arguments, a counterfactual analysis should be useful to answer the question posed by Buiter et al., 1998, De Grauwe, 1997, Wyplosz, 2004 and Wyplosz, 2006. Such approach is popular not only in history (e.g., Ferguson, 1997) but also in the process of European monetary integration. For instance, Barrel et al. (1996) view German Monetary Union as a sequence of large asymmetric shocks to the European economies. They perform historical counterfactual analysis by removing relevant events that we could not have anticipated, starting with the collapse of the centrally planned economies and the deterioration in the German fiscal position. Pesaran et al. (2005) use a global VAR approach to analyze the counterfactual scenarios of the U.K. in the Euro area. Dubois et al. (2007) simulate the costs and benefits of EMU membership if the euro had never been launched. They find that small members in the euro area like Finland, the Netherlands and Spain, seem to have benefitted from the pre-euro convergence and from the single currency regime. In this paper, we perform a counterfactual analysis to explore what would have happened if a European central bank (in this paper we call it “ecb” to distinguish it from the European Central Bank, the ECB) had been in existence before 1992, combining the settings proposed by Masson (2007), historical data and ECM estimation, and a simple four-player (Germany, France, U.K. and “ecb”) Nash game.3 Previous studies have used the historical descriptive method or global VAR to analyze the counterfactual scenarios of the U.K. in the Euro area. This study uses a game simulation to explore whether earlier implementation of policy coordination or a single monetary policy would have kept the U.K. in the process of European monetary integration. That is, our model can clearly infer possible welfare and policy responses of the countries involved. Whereas, this could not have been achieved by previous works. The rest of the article is structured as follows. Section 2 explains the modeling. Section 3 presents how to derive the different scenarios of policy coordination. Section 4 simulates the counterfactual scenarios with and without the “ecb”. Section 5 concludes.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

This paper explores whether a single monetary policy implemented earlier would have kept the U.K. in the process of European monetary integration. A counterfactual game simulation approach is used, and five scenarios are established for comparison with the actual historical records. Surprisingly, the final answer is negative. Furthermore, we get a more pessimistic result: our simulations do not support that the E3 would be better if the “ecb” were established earlier. Moreover, policy coordination cannot prevent the ERM from collapse. Let us call to mind that a pessimistic viewpoint held by Eichengreen (2000): “That Europe, where monetary cooperation was more highly developed than anywhere else in the world, was unable to respond to this crisis cooperatively is revealing of the obstacles to the collective management of exchange rates under even the most favorable circumstances. If Europe could not finesse these difficulties, it is hard to imagine that East Asia or Latin America could do better.” The simulation result here is of course very preliminary, yet highlights the need of establishing an effective international coordinating mechanism.