دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 21989
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

قراردادهای تشویقی واگذار شده در مدیریت پرتفولیو تحت شرایط محدودیت متغییر

عنوان انگلیسی
Incentive contracts in delegated portfolio management under VaR constraint
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
21989 2012 7 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Economic Modelling, Volume 29, Issue 5, September 2012, Pages 1679–1685

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
محدودیت - قرارداد تشویقی - مدیریت پرتفولیوهای محول شده - اطلاعات خصوصی
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
VaR constraint, Incentive contract, Delegated portfolio management, Private information
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  قراردادهای تشویقی واگذار شده در مدیریت پرتفولیو تحت شرایط محدودیت متغییر

چکیده انگلیسی

This paper studies the incentive effect of linear performance-adjusted contracts in delegated portfolio management under a value-at-risk (VaR) constraint. It is shown that a linear performance-based contract can provide incentives for the portfolio manager to work at acquiring private information under a VaR risk constraint. The expected utility and optimal effort of a risk-averse manager are increasing functions of the return sharing ratio in the contract. However, a risk constraint causes the portfolio manager to reduce effort in gathering private information, suggesting that the VaR constraint increases the moral hazard between the investor and the manager.

مقدمه انگلیسی

In the past few decades, the industry of delegated portfolio management has developed tremendously. Investors delegate professional investment managers to manage their wealth believing that portfolio managers possess the ability to collect, interpret, and apply profitably the information on risk and return of financial assets. However, because managerial ability and effort are not observable, investors have to design an appropriate compensation contract to induce managers to work hard to acquire better information in the market so as to reduce the agency cost. Although the performance-based linear incentive contract has been widely used in the delegated portfolio management industry, its incentive effect has not been fully developed theoretically, especially under various market or institutional complications. Stoughton (1993) and Admati and Pleiderer (1997) find that a linear contract cannot induce managers to work hard to acquire private information, which is the well-known “no-incentive” feature of linear contract under ideal market conditions. In addition, Admati and Pleiderer (1997) argue that the commonly used benchmark-adjusted compensation schemes are generally inconsistent with optimal risk‐sharing and do not lead to the choice of an optimal portfolio for the investor. This paper studies the linear incentive contract under a value-at-risk (VaR) constraint in a framework similar to Stoughton (1993) and Gomez and Sharma (2006) . As Jorion, 2003 and Jorion, 2007 and Pearson (2002) note, the fund management industry is increasingly using VaR to: (1) allocate assets among managers, (2) set risk limits, and (3) monitor asset allocations and managers (these activities are often referred to as ‘risk budgeting’). However, the incentive effect of linear contracts of delegated portfolio management under a VaR constraint has not been investigated in the literature. In this paper we show that a linear contract with a VaR risk constraint can raise the manager's efforts on information acquisition. A risk-averse manager's expected utility and optimal effort levels increase with the return sharing ratio, suggesting that a linear contract can not only allocate risks efficiently between the investor and the manager, but also induce the manager to work hard. Furthermore, under a VaR constraint, the manager's effort level is lower than that without such a constraint, suggesting that the VaR constraint increases the moral hazard between the investor and the manager. 1.1. Literature review Despite the somewhat surprising result in Stoughton (1993) , the linear contract is still the most popular contract in asset management due to its simplicity and intuitiveness. 1 Two strands of literature have addressed the no-incentive feature of linear contracts. 2 The first strand studies nonlinear incentive contract and the second strand investigates the impact of various practical complications or restrictions (some of which are discussed in Almazan et al., 2004 ) on the incentive effect of linear contracts. The general finding of these studies is that the practical complications (e.g., restriction on short-selling or the investment manager's possession of market power) can usually overcome the underinvestment of effort in the linear contract. In the first strand of literature, Bhattacharya and Pleiderer (1985) prove the existence of incentive contracts that can distinguish the types of managers and make the managers to truthfully reveal their ability and private information. In such a contract the compensation of the manager should be a quadratic function of the asset return. A nonlinear contract is optimal for investors with high risk tolerance. Ross (2004) examines the incentive effects of some common structures such as puts and calls, and briefly explores the duality between a fee schedule that makes an agent more or less risk‐averse, and gambles that increase or decrease risk. Li and Tiwari (2009) argue that a benchmark-adjusted option-type incentive can help overcome the problem of underinvestment in effort that undermines linear contracts. In the second strand of related literature, Gomez and Sharma (2006) and Agarwal et al. (2007) show that under short-sell constraints a linear contract can provide portfolio managers with incentives to gather information. Sheng and Yang (2010) demonstrate that when the manager has market power, that is, her asset selection can influence the equilibrium market price, a linear contract has incentive effects. Dybvig et al. (2010) show that trading restrictions are an essential part of an optimal contract because they prevent the manager from undoing the incentive effects of performance-based fees. Kyle et al. (2011) endogenize information acquisition and portfolio delegation in a one-period strategic trading model, and find that a higher powered linear contract induces the manager to exert more effort for information acquisition. Fabretti and Herzel (2012) consider the problem of how to establish compensation for a portfolio manager who is required to restrict the investment set because of socially responsible screening. Palomino and Prat (2003) show that when an agent can control the riskiness of the portfolio in a two-period model, the optimal contract is simply a bonus contract: the agent is paid a fixed sum if the portfolio return is above a certain threshold; in a multi-period framework, the optimal contract is linear. Heinkel and Stoughton (1994) also investigate the dynamics of portfolio management contracts in a two-period model. In delegated portfolio management, the manager wants to maximize her expected utility, but preferences on risk taking may differ between the investor and the manager. To protect her interest the investor may want to introduce risk constraints into the delegated portfolio management contract. Risk constraints can change investing opportunities and behavior of the manager. Jorion (2003) finds that adding a constraint on the total portfolio volatility can substantially improve the performance of an active portfolio. In a mean tracking error variance (TEV) framework, Alexander and Baptista (2008) find that a VaR constraint can mitigate the well-known problem that when an active manager seeks to track (or outperform) a benchmark, she may select a particularly inefficient portfolio. This paper falls into the second strand of literature by studying the incentive effect of a linear contract under a VaR risk constraint. 1.2. VaR in financial risk management The origin of VaR can be traced back to quantitative trading groups at several financial institutions in the 1980s, notably Bankers Trust, although neither the acronym “VaR” nor the definition were standardized. When the financial events of the early 1990s called for some measure on firm-wide risk, VaR was the natural choice because it was the only common risk measure that could be both defined for all businesses and aggregated without strong assumptions. In 1994, J. P. Morgan published the methodology, which, two years later, was spun off into an independent for-profit business now part of RiskMetrics Group. In 1997, the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission ruled that public corporations must disclose quantitative information about their derivatives activity. Major banks chose to implement the rule by including VaR information in the notes of their financial statements. Worldwide adoption of the Basel Accords since late 1990s gave further impetus to the use of VaR. In the meantime, many academic researches have studied its application and impact in portfolio management (e.g., Basak and Shapiro, 2001, Campbell et al., 2001, Jarrow and Zhao, 2006 and Natarajan et al., 2008). The current paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 describes the basic model employed. Section 3 outlines the results of Stoughton (1993) and Gomez and Sharma (2006) , used as a benchmark for our findings, which propose that there is no incentive effect in a linear contract. The VaR constraint is introduced in Section 4 . Section 5 studies the manager's utility function with a risk constraint. Section 6 investigates the impact of a VaR constraint on the incentive effect in a linear contract. Concluding remarks are in Section 7 .

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

This paper investigates the impact of a VaR constraint on a linear contract for delegated portfolio management within a principal-agent framework. Under a VaR constraint, increasing the return sharing ratio in the contract can increase the freedom for the manager when building the portfolio, and therefore partially lessen the impact of the risk constraint. A risk-averse manager's expected utility and optimal effort level increase with the return sharing ratio, so a linear contract can not only make the investor and the manager share risks efficiently, but also motivate the manager to gain high-quality private information, which is mutually beneficial to the manager and the investor. However, the manager's effort level is lower with a VaR constraint than without. This result shows that although a VaR constraint can limit the risk-taking behavior of the manager, it also lowers the manager's effort level, thus raising the moral hazard problem. Future research may investigate the optimal contract under a VaR constraint. Our preliminary work, however, indicates that such an optimal contract may not be available in a closed form.