دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 20575
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

سرمایه گذاری موجودی، تعامل جهانی و محدودیت های مالی در بریتانیا: شواهدی از میکروداده ها

عنوان انگلیسی
Inventory investment, global engagement, and financial constraints in the UK: Evidence from micro data
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
20575 2010 12 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Journal of Macroeconomics, Volume 32, Issue 1, March 2010, Pages 239–250

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
محدودیت های مالی - تعامل جهانی - سرمایه گذاری موجودی
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Financial constraints, Global engagement, Inventory investment,
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  سرمایه گذاری موجودی، تعامل جهانی و محدودیت های مالی در بریتانیا: شواهدی از میکروداده ها

چکیده انگلیسی

We use a panel of 9381 UK firms to study the links between firms’ global engagement status and their financial health. We estimate inventory investment equations augmented with a financial composition variable, and interpret the sensitivity of inventory investment to the latter as a measure of the strength of the financial constraints faced by firms. We find that smaller, younger, and more risky firms; and firms that do not export and are not foreign owned exhibit higher sensitivities. Moreover, global engagement substantially reduces the sensitivities displayed by the former categories of firms: this suggests that it shields firms from financial constraints.

مقدمه انگلیسی

A burgeoning literature has documented that, in an increasingly globalized world, exporters and foreign owned firms are larger, more productive, more capital-intensive, and pay higher wages than their purely domestic counterparts.1 Yet, the effects of being an exporter or foreign owned on other firm characteristics have received much less attention. This paper seeks to fill this gap in the literature, by using a large panel of UK firms to study whether the two dimensions of firms’ global participation, namely export behavior and foreign ownership, affect firms’ financial health. Only a handful of papers in the literature have looked at the effects of global engagement on firms’ financial health, obtaining contrasting results. Along the first dimension of global participation, Campa and Shaver (2002) find that liquidity constraints are less binding for Spanish exporters compared to non-exporters; while Castañeda (2002) shows that export-oriented Mexican firms faced higher financial constraints before the 1995–2000 financial paralysis than after. Along the second dimension, and focusing, respectively on Colombia, Côte D’Ivoire, and Estonia, Arbeláez and Echavarría, 2002 and Harrison and McMillan, 2003, and Mickiewicz et al. (2004) show that foreign owned firms face lower financial constraints compared to other firms. De Brun et al. (2002) find no such evidence for firms in Uruguay.2 All the above mentioned papers analyze financial constraints in the context of fixed investment regressions augmented with financial variables such as cash flow. In particular, they consider the sensitivity of investment to cash flow as an indicator of the degree of financial constraints faced by firms: financially constrained firms (for whom access to external finance is difficult and/or expensive) can only invest if they have sufficient internal funds. Our contribution to the literature is twofold. First, we study the effects of global engagement on firms’ financial health in the UK. This is important because most of the studies that looked at similar issues generally considered developing or transition countries. Our choice of the UK is motivated by the fact that this country ranks high in terms of global engagement: it is the fifth largest exporter of manufactures in the world and the second largest host of multinational enterprises. Moreover, a rich firm-level dataset is available for the UK, that covers mostly unlisted firms, which are generally small, young, and particularly likely to face financial constraints. We expect globally engaged firms to face a lower degree of financial constraints compared to their purely domestic counterparts for the following reasons. First, globally engaged firms have access to both internal and international financial markets, which enables them to diversify their sources of financing and the associated risks. Specifically, foreign owned firms can obtain credit from their parent company, insuring themselves against liquidity constraints (Desai et al., 2004).3 Second, as they benefit from a lower bankruptcy risk and adopt international standards faster in terms of product quality, foreign owned firms find it easier to gain access to domestic banks (Colombo, 2001 and Harrison and McMillan, 2003). Third, because they are also dependent on demand from foreign countries, exporters are less tied to the domestic cycle, and less subject to those financial constraints caused by tight monetary policy and recessions at home.4 This leads to a more stable cash flow for exporters compared to non-exporters, which in turn leads to weaker liquidity constraints (Campa and Shaver, 2002 and Garcia-Vega and Guariglia, 2008).5 Finally, being an exporter also provides a signal that the firm is sufficiently productive to generate enough profits in foreign markets to recover the sunk costs that need to be met when entering foreign markets for the first time (Roberts and Tybout, 1997). This increases the likelihood that the firm will be able to service its external debt, and further relaxes the liquidity constraints that it faces. Our second contribution to the literature is that we explore, for the first time, the links between firms’ global engagement and their financial health in the context of inventory investment regressions. We estimate error-correction inventory investment equations augmented with a financial composition variable. As in the investment literature, we interpret the coefficient on the latter as a measure of the degree of financial constraints faced by firms. We explore how this coefficient differs across firms classified into financially constrained and unconstrained in a traditional sense (based in turn on size, age, and risk), on the one hand; and across globally engaged and purely domestic, on the other. We also compare the coefficient across globally engaged financially constrained firms and purely domestic financially constrained firms, with the objective of determining whether global engagement can shield firms from financial constraints. Three reasons justify our choice of inventory investment in our analysis. First, because of its high liquidity and low adjustment costs, inventory investment is likely to be more sensitive to financial variables than investment in fixed capital (Carpenter et al., 1994). Second, inventory investment plays a crucial role in business cycle fluctuations (Blinder and Maccini, 1991). Third, inventory investment equations are less likely than fixed investment equations to suffer from misspecification due to the inappropriate control for investment opportunities.6 Our results show that smaller, younger, and more risky firms, on the one hand; and firms that are not globally engaged, on the other, exhibit higher sensitivities of inventory investment to our financial composition variable. Moreover, when we differentiate among purely domestic financially constrained firms, globally engaged financially constrained firms, and financially unconstrained firms, we find that the effects of our financial variable are statistically significant only for the former group, implying that global engagement helps firms to overcome liquidity constraints. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents some economic background for our analysis, and illustrates our baseline specification and our econometric methodology. In Section 3, we describe our data and present some descriptive statistics. Section 4 illustrates our main empirical results, and Section 5 concludes.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

We have used a panel of 9381 UK firms over the period 1993–2003 to study the links between firms’ global engagement status and their financial health. We have estimated error-correction inventory investment equations augmented with a financial composition variable, MIX, defined as the firm’s ratio of short-term debt to short-term debt plus trade credit. We have then analyzed the differential effects of MIX on the inventory accumulation of firms more and less likely to face financial constraints in a traditional sense, on the one hand; and of globally engaged versus purely domestic firms, on the other. In line with previous studies, our results suggest that MIX only affects inventory investment at firms that are financially constrained in a traditional sense (i.e. small, young, and risky firms). Moving beyond existing literature, we also found that inventory accumulation at globally engaged firms is not sensitive to MIX, whereas inventory investment at purely domestic firms is. This suggests that global engagement is associated with a lower degree of financial constraints. Finally, we have directly tested whether global engagement plays a role in attenuating the liquidity constraints faced by smaller, younger, and more risky firms. For this purpose we have analyzed the effects of MIX on the inventory investment of purely domestic financially constrained firms, globally engaged financially constrained firms, and financially unconstrained firms. We found that our financial variable only has a statistically significant effect on the inventory investment of the former category. We interpreted this as evidence that global engagement shields firms from liquidity constraints. From a policy viewpoint, these results suggest that export promotion policies and policies providing incentives to Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) may be beneficial to the economy, not only through their well-known direct growth-enhancing role, but also because they are likely to reduce the level of financial constraints faced by firms, and consequently to indirectly enhance their investment spending and productivity. The latter effect is particularly relevant for small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs), whose investment is often constrained by the lack of finance.