ادغام عمودی، بالا بردن هزینه های رقبا و تبانی بالادستی
کد مقاله | سال انتشار | تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی |
---|---|---|
1097 | 2009 | 20 صفحه PDF |
Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)
Journal : European Economic Review, Volume 53, Issue 4, May 2009, Pages 461–480
چکیده انگلیسی
This paper analyzes the impact vertical integration has on upstream collusion when the price of the input is linear. As a first step, the paper derives the collusive equilibrium that requires the lowest discount factor in the infinitely repeated game when one firm is vertically integrated. It turns out this is the joint-profit maximum of the colluding firms. The discount factor needed to sustain this equilibrium is then shown to be unambiguously lower than the one needed for collusion in the separated industry. While the previous literature has found it difficult to reconcile raising-rivals’-costs strategies following a vertical merger with equilibrium behavior in the static game, they are subgame perfect in the repeated game studied here.
مقدمه انگلیسی
The anticompetitive effects of vertical integration continue to be an active and controversial topic of research in industrial economics. Antitrust decisions hostile towards vertical mergers in the US in the 1950s and 1960s were based on the idea that vertical integration can harm competition by removing resources from the input market, thereby leveraging monopoly power from one market to another. These arguments have been labeled as naïve (Rey and Tirole, 2007) because they lacked a rigorous formal basis. The more recent post-Chicago theories of vertical mergers (for example, Salinger, 1988, Hart and Tirole, 1990 and O’Brien and Shaffer, 1992) formally derive many of the conclusions of the older theories. In game-theoretic models a connection is established between vertical integration and potentially anticompetitive outcomes. The post-Chicago theories of vertical integration differ in various details, for example, assumptions about the integrated firm's market power and the contractual arrangements between the parties involved. There are several dominating approaches though, including the “raising-rivals’-costs” and the “facilitating-collusion” theory (Riordan, 2008).1 The raising-rivals’-costs theory of vertical merger highlights the possibility that vertically integrated firms may drive up the price of the input its unintegrated downstream rivals pay. In a seminal contribution, Ordover et al. (1990), henceforth OSS (1990), argue that vertical mergers might change the incentive to compete in the input market. When a vertically integrated firm withdraws from the input market, upstream price competition becomes weaker. This reduction in upstream competition implies a higher price for the input which means higher cost for the non-integrated downstream firms. Since the downstream unit of the integrated firm benefits when its rivals’ costs are raised, the integrated firm is better off withdrawing from the market compared to the case where it competes in the input market. In other words, it pays for the integrated firm to forgo business with non-integrated downstream firms and instead gain from its downstream rivals becoming less competitive as a result of the increased the price of the input. The facilitating-collusion theory argues that vertical integration might make price agreements among upstream firms easier. This concern has been expressed in the 1984 Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines and in several cartel cases (see Riordan, 2008). The idea has recently been formalized in a dynamic model by Nocke and White (2007).2 They analyze collusion in the infinitely repeated game among upstream firms which charge two-part tariffs for the input. Nocke and White compare the minimum discount factor required for collusion where one or more firms are vertically integrated to the case of vertical separation. It turns out that vertical integration unambiguously facilitates collusion. This paper builds on and adds to both the raising-rivals’-costs and the facilitating-collusion theory of vertical integration.3 It combines OSS’ (1990) idea that raising-rivals’-costs effects change the incentives of vertically integrated firms to compete in the input market with the presumption that vertical integration facilitates collusion. In terms of the modeling strategy, the paper can merge these two strands of the literature because they share several central assumptions (e.g., bilateral oligopoly with perfect competition upstream and imperfect competition downstream). In this paper, the stage game is modeled as in OSS (1990) and allows for a raising-rivals’-costs effect but, in contrast to the static model of OSS (1990), this paper studies repeated interaction in a dynamic model. The analysis of the impact of vertical integration on collusion is similar to Nocke and White (2007). However, departing from Nocke and White (2007) and following OSS (1990), downstream firms pay a linear price for the input here. In a first step, the paper provides a general analysis of upstream collusion in the presence of an integrated firm. The analysis focuses on the collusive equilibrium that requires the lowest discount factor (see Compte et al., 2002, for a similar analysis). It turns out that this equilibrium is the one where the profits of the colluding firms are maximized. In other words, the payoff dominant equilibrium also relaxes the incentive constraint as far as possible. Other equilibria exist but they require a higher discount factor and give lower profits to the colluding players. A general finding of the analysis of collusion involving an integrated firm is that, because the integrated firm operates both upstream and downstream, collusive pricing is rather different from the standard case of upstream collusion among vertically separated firms. One of these differences is that the downstream unit of the integrated firm is involved in the collusion in that the price of the downstream integrated firm is higher than its myopic best reply. This result confirms and extends Chen's (2001) findings. Based on this preparatory analysis, the paper derives two main results. First, the paper's contribution to the raising-rivals’-costs literature is to show that an outcome similar to the one analyzed in OSS (1990) can actually be sustained as a subgame perfect Nash equilibrium. Second, the contribution to the facilitating collusion theory is that vertical integration facilitates collusion also with linear contracts. To appraise these findings, more background information and details of the results are needed. Regarding the significance of the first main result, one needs to recall that OSS’ raising-rivals’-costs argument has been criticized as not robust. Hart and Tirole (1990) and Reiffen (1992) pointed out that, even though withdrawing from the input market is a profitable strategy for the integrated firm ex ante, it has an incentive to compete in the input market ex post. Therefore, vertical integration does not make any difference at all in the static Nash equilibrium. The intuition of this argument is that, since the price of the input increases once the integrated firm withdraws from the input-good market, the integrated firm has an incentive to deviate. Rather than withdraw from the input market, it will re-enter and undercut the upstream competitors’ price in order to gain the business of the non-integrated downstream firms. The integrated firm's upstream rivals will anticipate such a deviation and will expect the re-entry in the market. In that case, upstream competition is the same as without vertical integration in the static game. Several papers in the literature have shown before that the outcome OSS (1990) propose can be made robust and compatible with Nash equilibrium behavior (see OSS, 1992; Choi and Yi, 2000 and Church and Gandal, 2000).4 However, these papers are only partially successful in confirming the OSS (1990) approach as they circumvent, to some extent, the problem posed in the original analysis. For example, in OSS (1992), non-integrated downstream firms procure the input in a descending-price auction. In such a scenario, the integrated firm will drop out early in the auction, the input market will be monopolized by the non-integrated upstream firm and, hence, the outcome is indeed as in OSS (1990). Note that deviation from this equilibrium is prevented by the rules of the auction. By dropping out, the integrated firm commits itself not to re-enter. Thus, if available, commitment works in this case, but this does not answer the question raised by Hart and Tirole (1990) and Reiffen (1992). Their point is whether commitment will be available at all, and why vertical merger should enable to commit. Arguably, few markets are organized as descending-price auctions. Therefore, it is still subject to debate whether the rasing-rivals’-costs theory has implications beyond the perhaps somewhat restrictive scenarios the literature has hitherto suggested.5 The present paper does not impose any assumptions on the extensive form that seem overly narrow. The assumption of repeated interaction is simple and should be plausible for many industries. What the paper shows is that, even though the raising-rivals’-costs strategy is not tenable as an equilibrium of the static game, it can be supported in the repeated game if repetition is frequent enough. This result confirms the informal arguments of Riordan and Salop (1995) that OSS’ (1990) rasing-rivals’-costs idea can be saved from the Hart and Tirole (1990) and Reiffen (1992) criticism with repeated interaction.
نتیجه گیری انگلیسی
This paper analyzes upstream collusion in the presence of a vertically integrated firm when downstream firms pay a linear price for the input. In the model, the downstream unit of the integrated firm benefits from a raising-rivals’-costs effect when the input market is collusive. While this raising-rivals’-costs strategy (OSS, 1990) is not an equilibrium in the static game (Hart and Tirole, 1990 and Reiffen, 1992), this paper shows that it is a subgame perfect Nash equilibrium in the repeated game. A central result of the paper is that, in a separated industry, a single vertical merger facilitates upstream collusion, that is, it causes a reduction of the minimum discount factor required for collusion. Thus, firms have an incentive for anticompetitive vertical merger. This complements the analysis of Nocke and White (2007) who prove the same result in a model with two-part tariffs. Interestingly, the effects underlying this result (punishment, outlets and reaction effect) turn out to be work rather similarly with linear prices and two-part tariffs. In contrast to the two-part tariffs model, however, the overall welfare balance of vertical integration is not necessarily negative with linear tariffs. The integrated firm delivers its downstream unit at marginal cost, and this elimination of a double markup can imply a welfare gain compared to the case where vertically separated firms collude. Alternative scenarios, including counter merger and downstream collusion, do not generally eliminate the incentive for vertical merger. The paper further adds to the foreclosure debate (see, e.g., Riordan, 2008). When upstream firms successfully collude, they reduce demand. This would be foreclosure in the broad definition of Rey and Tirole (2007). They define any case where downstream firms have incomplete access to the input good as foreclosure. OSS (1990) suggest a more specific notion of foreclosure where the integrated firm withdraws from the input market. In the model of this paper, the integrated firm is active in the input market and its market share is always positive (in an example with linear demand, the market share can even plausibly be above 50%), so this result does not support OSS’ (1990) idea of foreclosure. When the downstream unit of the integrated firm operates as a profit center, the case for OSS-type foreclosure is stronger. In this case, the market share of the integrated firm is less than a symmetric market division would suggest. Thus, there is at least partial foreclosure.