دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 1300
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

تعدیل انگیزه های ضمنی : مزایای الگوبرداری در مدیریت پول

عنوان انگلیسی
Offsetting the implicit incentives: Benefits of benchmarking in money management
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
1300 2008 11 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Journal of Banking & Finance, Volume 32, Issue 9, September 2008, Pages 1883–1893

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
الگوبرداری - جریان صندوق - انگیزه های ضمنی - ریسک - مدیریت ریسک - انتخاب پرتفوی -
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  تعدیل انگیزه های ضمنی : مزایای الگوبرداری در مدیریت پول

چکیده انگلیسی

Money managers are rewarded for increasing the value of assets under management. This gives a manager an implicit incentive to exploit the well-documented positive fund-flows to relative-performance relationship by manipulating her risk exposure. The misaligned incentives create potentially significant deviations of the manager’s policy from that desired by fund investors. In the context of a familiar continuous-time portfolio choice model, we demonstrate how a simple risk management practice that accounts for benchmarking can ameliorate the adverse effects of managerial incentives. Our results contrast with the conventional view that benchmarking a fund manager is not in the best interest of investors.

مقدمه انگلیسی

The money management industry has been growing at a mind-boggling pace. More and more individual investors’ money is put into the care of professional managers. The question of these managers’ incentives is thus of utmost importance to households and policymakers. Incentives of individual investors and professional managers are not always perfectly aligned. In particular, contrary to investors’ objectives, managers take into account of their performance relative to some index in their portfolio choice. This is because capital inflows into funds follow good relative performance. Therefore, a significant factor in a rational fund manager’s decision problem is an implicit incentive that arises from the relationship between fund flows and her performance relative to an index. Previous research has shown that if the manager is unrestricted in her portfolio choice, she has an incentive to boost the riskiness of her portfolio when underperforming her index and lock in her gains upon catching up.3 In this paper, we consider mechanisms aimed at limiting such behavior. Towards this, we consider risk management practices that account for benchmarking. Establishing an economic role for such widely observed practices is also of independent theoretical interest given the arguments made against them in the academic literature (Roll, 1992 and Admati and Pfleiderer, 1997). We focus on a simple constraint, referred to as a “minimum performance constraint” or a “benchmarking restriction,” which prohibits a shortfall in the manager’s return relative to a reference portfolio to exceed a pre-specified level over a certain horizon. If a manager violates the constraint, she incurs a large penalty; in our model, we assume that she simply loses her job.4 This simple, yet versatile, constraint is also closely related to some popular risk management practices such as stop-loss limits, portfolio insurance, value-at-risk (VaR) and tracking error limits. Such a constraint can be either explicitly or implicitly imposed on the manager by her superiors. The parameter governing the stringency of the benchmarking restriction in our model is the manager’s allowed shortfall relative to the benchmark. We demonstrate that as the (appropriate) benchmarking restriction becomes more stringent, the impact of the fund-flows induced incentives on the manager’s policy weakens, and beyond a certain allowed shortfall the convexity in the flow-performance relationship ceases to have an effect on the manager’s optimal policy. Absent the benchmarking restriction, the asset allocation choice of the manager is not necessarily in the best interest of fund investors, who care about the risk and return of their investment and not about attracting capital into the fund. Moreover, the risk tolerance of fund investors need not coincide with that of the fund manager. We compare the manager’s policy when acting in the best interest of fund investors with when following an asset allocation policy optimal from her viewpoint. A simple calibration reveals that the costs of misaligned incentives could be quite significant. Most of our cost estimates, measured in units of an investor’s initial wealth, are within the 1.4–8.0% range. We show that a benchmark that is less risky than the index can temper deviations from the investors’ desired risk exposure in states where the manager is tempted to deviate the most, and hence is beneficial. Across most of our calibrations, the percentage loss recouped (in terms of the investor’s initial wealth) by benchmarking the manager ranges from 60% to 80%. Our results thus provide a rationale for benchmarking-type restrictions observed in this industry. Our analysis, however, also demonstrates how complicated fine-tuning the manager’s behavior may be in the presence of implicit flow-driven incentives. Indeed, as we illustrate, when the benchmark is (sufficiently) riskier than the index, benchmarking the manager may actually exacerbate her risk exposure. Our work is related to the literature on (adverse) consequences of benchmarking. In a mean-variance setting, Roll (1992) argues that benchmarking a money manager to an index results in her choosing a portfolio that is not mean-variance efficient. Admati and Pfleiderer (1997), in a similar context but with an asymmetrically informed investor and portfolio manager, also advocate against benchmarking the manager, and particularly linking compensation to the types of benchmarks observed in practice. The spirit of these results is that, in an economy without fund-flows induced considerations, benchmarking induces a manager to deviate from choosing a mean-variance efficient portfolio that is desired by investors (with mean-variance preferences). Our viewpoint is that money managers are concerned with attracting fund inflows, which we accept as a fact of life. The role of our benchmarking restriction is to (partially) alleviate the adverse effects of the ensuing managerial incentives, thus benefitting investors. There is a strand of literature, growing out of Bhattacharya and Pfleiderer (1985), investigating optimal contracting in the context of delegated portfolio management, where the manager typically has superior information or ability, or expends costly effort. In this vein is also Starks (1987). Dybvig et al. (2001) consider restrictions on the investment opportunity set (trading strategies) as part of an optimal contract, while Gómez and Sharma (2006) analyze the effect of short-selling constraints on a manager’s optimal contract. Also within a static principal-agent framework, Agarwal et al. (2007) study the incentive effects of relative (to a benchmark) performance evaluation in the presence of portfolio constraints. In a dynamic portfolio choice model, Cadenillas et al. (2004) consider a principal-agent problem in which a risk-averse manager compensated with options chooses the riskiness of the projects she invests in. Our focus in this paper is different. Instead of solving for an optimal contract, we look for alternative mechanisms aimed at counteracting the manager’s adverse incentives.5 In that spirit, Jorion (2003) further analyzes Roll’s static setup and considers how imposing additional constraints can move optimal portfolios closer to mean-variance efficiency, while Alexander and Baptista (in press) extends Jorion’s work by incorporating a VaR constraint. Brennan, 1993 and Gómez and Zapatero, 2003 study the equilibrium implications of Roll-type setting and derive a two-beta CAPM. Closer to our message is van Binsbergen et al. (in press), who also advocate the use of benchmarking in money management. Their way of addressing benchmarking, however, differs from ours in that they model managers as deriving utility from the ratio of their terminal portfolio value over a benchmark. Hence, unlike in our analysis, the managers care only about relative performance, and not absolute. The ensuing effects of the benchmark on the managers’ behavior are also different. Since managers are risk averse in van Binsbergen et al., they try to reduce the variability of the portfolio-benchmark ratio even when outperforming the benchmark. In our setting, the manager is affected disproportionately more when her performance relative to the benchmark is poor. Basak et al. (2007) examine fund-flows induced incentives of fund managers. The special case of our manager’s choice being unrestricted coincides with theirs. However, they do not examine the effects of restricting the manager’s investment policy, which is the goal of this paper. There is also a recent literature examining benchmarking absent adverse incentives and fund-flows considerations. In a dynamic setting like ours, Teplá, 2001 and Basak et al., 2006 study the optimal policies of an agent subject to a benchmarking restriction. Our formulation that incorporates simultaneously both the fund-flows and benchmarking considerations permits a study of the economic role of investment restrictions, the main focus of this paper. In particular, the insights of our analysis here cannot be gained from examining the benchmarking restriction or the fund-flows induced incentives alone. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the model primitives and discusses the fund-flows induced implicit incentives and the benchmarking restriction. Section 3 derives the manager’s optimal policy under benchmarking, and Section 4 evaluates cost/benefits of benchmarking to investors. Section 5 concludes, and the Appendix provides the proofs and other material omitted in the body of the paper.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

In this paper, we have demonstrated how benchmarking an active money manager to a safer portfolio and imposing limits on her allowed shortfall can be beneficial. This is because the incentives induced by the compensation package may tempt the manager to not act in the best interest of investors and in particular take on excessive risk. The benchmarking restriction we primarily focus on in this paper benefits fund investors. However, as our analysis demonstrates, not all benchmarks necessarily create value for investors – for example, a too-aggressive a benchmark may in fact destroy value. Hence, it is important to take into account of investors’ risk tolerance when selecting benchmarks for money managers. Our study leaves aside many possible constraints that may also be beneficial. We believe that endogenizing investment restrictions in the context of active money management is a fruitful area for future research. It would also be of interest to endogenize within our model the fund-flows to relative-performance relationship that we have taken as given.