دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 1308
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

ارزیابی عملکرد و شاخص معیار خود طراحی شده در صنعت صندوق سرمایه گذاری مشترک

عنوان انگلیسی
Performance evaluation and self-designated benchmark indexes in the mutual fund industry
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
1308 2009 15 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Journal of Financial Economics, Volume 92, Issue 1, April 2009, Pages 25–39

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
- صندوق سرمایه گذاری مشترک - ارزیابی عملکرد - معیار ها - جریان - انگیزه های استراتژیک -
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Mutual funds,Performance evaluation,Benchmarks,Flows,Strategic incentives,
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  ارزیابی عملکرد و شاخص معیار خود طراحی شده در صنعت صندوق سرمایه گذاری مشترک

چکیده انگلیسی

Almost one-third of actively managed, diversified U.S. equity mutual funds specify a size and value/growth benchmark index in the fund prospectus that does not match the fund's actual style. Nevertheless, these “mismatched” benchmarks matter to fund investors. Performance relative to the specified benchmark is a significant determinant of a fund's subsequent cash inflows, even controlling for performance measures that better capture the fund's style. These incremental flows appear unlikely to be rational responses to abnormal returns. The evidence is consistent with the notion that mismatched self-designated benchmarks result from strategic fund behavior driven by the incentive to improve flows.

مقدمه انگلیسی

Performance evaluation theory stresses the importance of using good benchmarks (Holmstrom, 1979). For example, when determining an airline CEO's bonus, comparing the firm's performance to that of other airlines can improve efficiency by helping to filter out common shocks that are beyond the CEO's control. It would be less efficient to use railroads as the benchmark instead because shocks to the two industries are not perfectly correlated, yet the CEO has an incentive to encourage the use of a railroad benchmark if he believes that airlines are likely to outperform railroads. Of course, the attempt is unlikely to succeed in this setting because a knowledgeable corporate board of directors will realize that railroads are not the best benchmark. In other settings, however, performance evaluation is undertaken by less sophisticated principals than corporate boards. These principals may have limited ability to distinguish useful benchmarks from less useful ones, which may in turn create incentives for agents to try to strategically influence which benchmark is used. There is little systematic evidence on these issues because it is difficult to observe agents’ preferred benchmarks and whether principals pay attention to them. This paper provides such evidence from the mutual fund industry, in which fund investors take the role of unsophisticated principal. Funds’ preferred benchmarks are available as a result of the SEC requirement that each fund's prospectus tabulate the fund's historical returns alongside those of a passive benchmark index. The SEC does not regulate which index is used as the benchmark, instead leaving the choice to the fund. This institutional setting maps naturally into the general issues mentioned above. Some funds’ self-designated benchmarks may not do a very good job capturing their exposures to common factors in returns, and so may not be very helpful in evaluating funds’ skill at generating abnormal returns. Moreover, at least some mutual fund investors may not be sophisticated enough to see through this when making decisions about purchases and sales of mutual funds, and thereby may not behave in a manner consistent with theories of optimal performance evaluation such as Holmstrom (1979). If so, such “mismatched” benchmarks might make sense to funds from a strategic perspective (Gibbons and Murphy, 1990). I use a new database of these self-designated mutual fund benchmark indexes to present evidence consistent with all of these possibilities. While this paper is about performance evaluation in the mutual fund industry, which is important in its own right because of the industry's size and importance to the economy, the evidence contributes more generally to the literature on the efficiency and incentive consequences of performance evaluation schemes (e.g., Ehrenberg and Bognanno, 1990). The evidence also contributes to three major branches of the mutual fund literature: that on how mutual fund managers are and should be evaluated (e.g., Kothari and Warner, 2001; Cohen, Coval, and Pastor, 2005; Warner and Wu, 2005); that on the determinants of mutual fund flows (e.g., Chevalier and Ellison, 1997 and Sirri and Tufano, 1998); and that on strategic behavior by mutual funds (e.g., Brown, Harlow, and Starks, 1996; Chevalier and Ellison, 1997 and Chevalier and Ellison, 1999). Especially relevant is the literature that, like this paper, shows that mutual fund flows appear at times to respond (or fail to respond) in irrational ways. Such papers include Musto (1999), Elton, Gruber, and Busse (2004), Cooper, Gulen, and Rau (2005), and Cronqvist (2006). I begin by showing that the vast majority of actively managed, diversified U.S. equity funds use a S&P or Russell benchmark index that is defined on size and value/growth dimensions. Because Fama and French (1992) and many others find that size and value/growth are associated with average returns and return covariances, for such a benchmark to be maximally useful in netting out priced common factors in returns, it should match the fund's exposure to size and value/growth factors. Yet this is frequently not the case. In fact, 31.2% of these funds specify a benchmark index that is “mismatched”: alternative S&P or Russell size and value/growth-based benchmarks both better match these funds’ size and value/growth characteristics and, more importantly, are more correlated with their returns. I refer to these as funds’ “corrected” benchmarks. Among these funds, the average excess return R2R2 with the actual benchmark is 70.6%, versus 82.6% with the corrected benchmark. I then ask whether mismatched self-designated benchmarks influence fund flows. Do fund investors respond to performance relative to a mismatched benchmark when making decisions about purchases and sales of mutual funds? For this to happen, at least some investors must pay attention to the information in fund prospectuses. According to a recent survey by the Investment Company Institute, the national association of investment companies, 34% of fund investors consult the fund prospectus before purchasing a mutual fund.1 This figure seems large enough to plausibly have an effect on flows, especially considering that the performance table is prominently displayed in the first few pages of the prospectus. Fund advertising also frequently features a comparison of the fund's performance with that of a benchmark (when the comparison is favorable). In fact, fund investors do pay attention to mismatched benchmarks when directing flows. A fund's performance relative to its self-designated but mismatched benchmark is a significant determinant of its subsequent cash inflows, even controlling for performance measures that better capture the fund's exposure to size and value/growth factors in returns. This is especially true for funds that beat those mismatched benchmarks. This result is robust to a variety of controls and specifications of functional form intended to capture nonlinearities in the relation between flows and performance (Chevalier and Ellison, 1997 and Sirri and Tufano, 1998). In particular, the effect is not due to investors simply comparing performance to the S&P 500 regardless of the actual self-designated benchmark. How should we interpret these results on flows? Is the response of flows to performance relative to a mismatched self-designated benchmark more likely to reflect rational or irrational behavior on the part of fund investors? From a performance evaluation/contracting perspective, because mutual funds generally receive a fixed percentage of assets under management as a fee, cash inflows and outflows are the mechanism by which fund investors (principals) influence fund companies’ (agents) compensation. As such, agency theory (e.g., Holmstrom, 1979) predicts that investors ought to direct flows in response to risk-adjusted return. Doing so aligns fund companies’ desire for increased compensation, which gives them the incentive to take actions to increase flows, with fund investors’ interest, maximizing risk-adjusted return. Thus, the acid test for the interpretation of these flows is whether mismatched benchmarks have incremental power to explain the cross-section of expected returns, and thereby help measure risk-adjusted returns. While one cannot completely rule out this possibility because the pricing kernel is unobservable to the econometrician, I conduct pricing tests that suggest that it is unlikely. As such, it appears unlikely that the incremental response of flows to performance relative to a mismatched benchmark is a rational response to abnormal returns. I believe the evidence more likely reflects a behavioral element to the composition of mutual fund flows, consistent with Musto (1999), Elton, Gruber, and Busse (2004), Cooper, Gulen, and Rau (2005), and Cronqvist (2006). I estimate that the magnitude of the expected incremental gain in flows to funds with mismatched self-designated benchmarks is 2.3% of assets under management per year, which is 14.6% of the average annual flow to those funds (15.8% of assets). These incremental flows create strategic incentives for funds to self-designate mismatched benchmarks in the first place: mismatched benchmarks can improve funds’ expected flows. Several pieces of evidence suggest that mismatched self-designated benchmarks may reflect funds’ strategic incentives. First, mismatched self-designated benchmarks are not typically a result of style drift or changing fund styles and so do not appear incidental. Second, value funds are more likely than growth funds to have self-designated benchmarks that are mismatched on value/growth and small-cap funds are more likely than large-cap funds to have self-designated benchmarks that are mismatched on size. These findings are consistent with fund attempts to improve expected flows by taking advantage of the size and value effects documented by Banz (1981) and Fama and French (1992), among others. Third, mismatched self-designated benchmarks are more common among large and high-fee funds, to which the benefit from a given increase in flows (defined as a percentage of assets under management) is larger. Finally, fund family effects are significant determinants of whether a fund has a mismatched self-designated benchmark, again suggesting that mismatched benchmarks are not incidental or random. Overall, the evidence in this paper further emphasizes the need, recently stressed by Goetzmann, Ingersoll, Spiegel, and Welch (2007), for the development and dissemination of measures of mutual fund performance that are both well grounded in economic theory and not subject to gaming. As mentioned above, this paper is related and contributes to several strands of literature. It is related to the body of work studying (possibly naive) consumer decisions in the mutual fund industry and the determinants of mutual fund flows. In addition to the papers cited above, Ippolito (1992) and Lynch and Musto (2003) are prominent papers in this literature. The strategic interpretation of mismatched benchmarks is consistent with evidence of strategic fund behavior in other contexts documented by, among others, Brown, Harlow, and Starks (1996), Chevalier and Ellison, 1997 and Chevalier and Ellison, 1999, Brown and Goetzmann (1997), Cooper, Gulen, and Rau (2005), and Cohen and Schmidt (2007). The frequency of mismatched self-designated benchmarks is consistent with Elton, Gruber, and Blake (2003), who study a sample of 108 funds and find that funds have substantial exposures to size and value/growth factors in returns that are not captured by their benchmarks, and with Cremers and Petajisto (2007), who find that funds typically have a high proportion of holdings that differ from those of the fund's theoretically correct benchmark index. Mismatched benchmarks that complicate the task of identifying a fund's true factor exposures and lead to excess flows are consistent with theoretical work such as Carlin (2008), who argues that financial service providers have incentives to strategically complicate their pricing schedules because they can earn economic rents in equilibrium from doing so. Finally, from the perspective of performance evaluation theory, mismatched self-designated benchmarks among mutual funds may be viewed as an example of the phenomenon described by Gibbons and Murphy (1990), in which an agent subject to relative performance evaluation chooses a reference group other than the one preferred by the principal.2 In a corporate setting, Murphy (1995) reports strategic choices of peer groups used for performance comparisons in company annual reports, though he is not able to test whether these peer groups matter to consumers of annual reports. This paper proceeds as follows. The next section describes the data. Section 3 compares funds to their benchmarks, remaining agnostic regarding whether benchmark choices appear strategic. Section 4 analyzes investor reaction to mismatched benchmarks in terms of flows, and discusses the interpretation and magnitude of these flows. Section 5 considers whether mismatched benchmarks are plausibly attributed to strategic behavior. Section 6 concludes.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

This paper shows that 31.2% of equity mutual funds specify an S&P or Russell size and value/growth-based benchmark index in the fund prospectus that is “mismatched”: alternative S&P or Russell size and value/growth-based benchmarks both better match these funds’ size and value/growth characteristics and are more correlated with their returns. Nevertheless, these mismatched self-designated benchmarks matter to fund investors. Performance relative to the specified benchmark, especially above the benchmark, is a significant determinant of a fund's subsequent cash inflows, even controlling for performance measures that better capture the fund's style. These incremental flows appear unlikely to be rational responses to abnormal returns, and provide a strategic incentive for funds to have benchmarks and portfolios that systematically differ in their risk attributes. I find several pieces of evidence that, taken together, suggest that mismatched self-designated benchmarks may be due to funds’ strategic incentives to improve inflows. Overall, the evidence in this paper further emphasizes the need, recently stressed by Goetzmann, Ingersoll, Spiegel, and Welch (2007), for the development and dissemination of measures of mutual fund performance that are both well grounded in economic theory and not subject to gaming.