دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 5851
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

چارچوب بهینه سازی برای پرداختن به گونه های مهاجم آبزی

عنوان انگلیسی
An optimization framework for addressing aquatic invasive species
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
5851 2013 11 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Ecological Economics, Volume 91, July 2013, Pages 69–79

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
- تصفیه آب بالاست - مدل بیو اقتصادی - گونه های مهاجم بیگانه - برنامه نویسی پویا تصادفی - آلودگی حرارتی
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  چارچوب بهینه سازی برای پرداختن به گونه های مهاجم آبزی

چکیده انگلیسی

This study develops a bio-economic model framework to optimize the management of aquatic invasive species. Stochastic dynamic programming is applied to investigate when and to what extent a society should engage in efforts to reduce the likelihood of an invasion, to control and eradicate a newly established population, and to adapt to damages. The framework is parameterized for a potential Asian clam (Corbicula fluminea) invasion in the warm water discharge area of a nuclear power plant planned on the northern shores of the Baltic Sea. The sensitivity analysis reveals three distinct strategies: an adaptive strategy, which reduces the damage that an existing invasive species population causes to the private sector; a preventive strategy, which delays the invasion and the resulting damage; and a mitigative strategy, which puts effort into timely detection, control and eradication of the newly established population. Choice of the optimal strategy is sensitive to the unit costs and effectiveness of the measures required, to the level of externalities and to the size of the clam population after the invasion has been detected. The results emphasize the need for the energy sector to identify and internalize the external costs of potential invasions when making any large-scale investment plans.

مقدمه انگلیسی

The introduction of invasive species has been identified as one of the major threats to aquatic ecosystems, where the alien species cause biodiversity loss and adverse environmental, economic and social impacts (Leppäkoski et al., 2002, Occhipinti-Ambrogi and Savini, 2003 and Pimentel et al., 2005). The eradication of aquatic invasive species after they become established is very difficult. Accordingly, managers and policy makers should pay attention to preventing introduction of potential invasive species. Then again, preventive measures and policies should be economically viable. This raises questions such as whether the expected benefits of preventive measures are likely to exceed their cost and how much society should invest in reducing the probability of invasion in comparison to post-invasion measures geared to controlling the population and adapting to damage. The principal global pathway by which aquatic invasive species are introduced is ship traffic, which causes transfers by ballast water, sediments and ship fouling (Molnar et al., 2008). Ship traffic is an efficient vector that enables alien species to overcome natural dispersal barriers, such as vast oceans. Larger ship sizes and drive speeds have increased the number of successful invasions globally. According to Molnar et al. (2008), over 80% of all identified aquatic invasions have been unintentional and 31% have occurred via ballast water. In the Baltic Sea, more than 50% of all introductions occur via shipping (Zaiko et al., 2011). Thermal pollution areas located near the warm water discharge outlets of power plants are typical gateways for aquatic invasive species entering the area from warmer environments. One such species is the Asian clam (Corbicula fluminea), a small bivalve that is native to Southeast Asia. It has been spreading rapidly worldwide in recent decades ( Darrigran, 2002, McMahon, 2002 and Sousa, 2008). It was purposely introduced on the west coast of North America in the early 1900s and has since spread to occupy ponds, lakes, streams and reservoirs virtually throughout the United States (Vaughn and Spooner, 2006 and references therein). It was first reported in Europe in the Minho estuary, Spain, in 1989 (Araujo et al., 1993) and is now a major component of the benthic fauna there in terms of density and biomass, accounting for more than 95% of the overall benthos biomass (Sousa, 2008). The clam is a freshwater species which tolerates salinities up to 13 PSU, and thus its further spread to estuaries and brackish seas is possible. It has been shown to aggressively outcompete native invertebrates (Karatayev et al., 2003), foul water intake pipes (Eng, 1979), alter benthic habitats (Hakenkamp et al., 2001) and diminish the recreational value of public beaches (Pimentel et al., 2005). Fouling at power plants has caused problems and costs and has been eradicated using either mechanical means or continuous chlorination ( Goss and Cain, 1975 and Satpathy et al., 2010). Mechanical cleansing requires shutting down and dewatering a power plant, resulting in severe economic losses, while chlorination may affect the aquatic ecosystem outside the discharge pipes. Optimal management of the risk of invasive species is a rather new, but increasingly popular topic in the economic literature. The principal modeling approach adopted in the case of already established nonindigenous species has been a continuous-time optimal control (Olson and Roy, 2002, Eiswerth and Johnson, 2002 and Buhle et al., 2005). Other optimal control models include those of Knowler and Barbier (2000), who analyzed the economic consequences of invasion in a predator–prey setting, and Ranjan et al. (2008), who extended the modeling framework to include options for both preventing an invasion and mitigating its impacts. In an example of a discrete-time application for an aquatic invasive species, Leung et al. (2002) developed an optimization framework to quantify the relative merits of different management strategies. Their model was parameterized for a representative lake with a power plant before a potential zebra mussel (Dreissena polymorpha) invasion. Fernandez (2007) emphasized that ships are the primary channel for aquatic species transportation and developed a game-theoretic model for aquatic trade where ports in different countries minimize their costs from the damage caused and abatement measures occasioned by invasive species. Cooperative and preventive abatements were found to be optimal vis-à-vis other policies. Levente and Phaneuf (2009) combined the demand for recreational boating with an ecological model describing the spatial and temporal spread of zebra mussels in Wisconsin and demonstrated that accounting for the behavioral responses of boaters is essential to the effectiveness of particular policies. There are no corresponding studies investigating optimal management of Asian clam invasions. Rosa et al. (2011) carried out a survey to evaluate the costs of the Asian clam invasion in Portugal, which was the gateway for this species to Europe some 30 years ago. The researchers show that as of 2010 the invasion had caused only minor costs to agriculture and different industries, including drinking water treatment and thermal power, but concluded that the costs may increase markedly in the near future as the invasion reaches the stage of full colonization. Earlier experiences from other invasive clam species (e.g. McMahon and Williams, 1986) suggest that serious infestations of sites such as nuclear power plants may not occur until as many as 50 years after the first observations. The objective of the present study is to build up a modeling framework that can be used in ex-ante analyses of how to manage aquatic invasive species. The framework allows us to simultaneously consider the quantity of resources to be allocated in reducing the probability of an invasion or in adapting to or mitigating its negative externalities. The management problem can be formulated from the point of view of either the social planner or the private sector. The problem is solved by the use of stochastic dynamic programming, which is a powerful tool for solving sequential and discrete-time management problems. Stochastic dynamic programming has been used earlier in determining how to best manage invasive species in both terrestrial (Eiswerth and Van Kooten, 2002 and Bogich and Shea, 2008) and aquatic ecosystems (Leung et al., 2002). As an extension to earlier studies, we consider both private and social costs and include all four general policies – prevention, eradication, control and adaptation (Finnoff et al., 2010) – as decision variables to respond to the risk of an invasive species and the associated damages. Our approach is suited particularly well to examining both the optimal timing and the optimal magnitude of prevention, eradication, control and adaptation simultaneously—as opposed to studying these separately and in a deterministic setting. It can contribute to the literature by taking into account how new information about the state of a clam invasion and its associated risks affect the optimal magnitude and timing of different management options. We construct a case study and examine crucial factors such as causes of mortality and age class structure, which drive the population dynamics and expansion of the clam population in the case study area and are thus important when determining the optimal decision. The model is parameterized for a potential Asian clam invasion in the northern Baltic Sea, where a planned nuclear power plant is likely to cause heat pollution in its water discharge area. This paper consists of four sections. The next section describes the overall modeling framework, depicts the case study area, defines the decision variables reflecting different mitigation and adaptation policies, and presents a cohort model describing the dynamics of the invasive species population. In addition, it details the costs and effectiveness of control measures and the costs of externalities and explains how the management problem was solved. The third section presents the numerical results and examines how the probability and consequences of the putative clam invasion are affected by the choice of decision variables. We also consider optimal strategies under different parameter assumptions. The fourth section discusses the key findings and caveats of the research.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

Investing in preventive, mitigative or adaptive measures when facing the risk of invasions by harmful alien species is an important decision for a society. This paper has analyzed when and to which extent four different measures should be applied to manage the risk of an Asian clam invasion in one delimited case study area. Our results demonstrate that the optimal management strategy is conditional on and sensitive to the expected costs of different measures and externalities imposed on different economic sectors. Even a small change in one or two parameters may trigger quite different solutions. For example, our results suggest that with the baseline cost parameters used in this study, the society should not invest in reducing the risk of an Asian clam invasion in the heat pollution zone of the planned nuclear power plant, but rather let the power company adapt to the consequences of the potential invasion. On the other hand, reduced unit costs of ballast water treatment (a preventive measure) trigger quite a different solution, in which the society imposes an immediate requirement on shipping companies to clean ballast water. Ballast water treatment also becomes economically attractive if the expected damage to recreation from the clam invasion is high enough or if ballast water treatment reduces the probability of invasion adequately. This latter result is particularly important, as such an improvement should be relatively easy and cheap to achieve through improved quality control and enforcement. This paper presents a framework for simultaneously considering optimal allocation of effort between pre- and post-invasion measures. The optimal solutions presented are driven by the specific features of the case study and cannot be generalized to other regions or species. However, the framework as such is amenable to both aquatic and terrestrial ecosystems. The dynamic programming framework can accommodate several sources of uncertainty in events or processes that are either truly stochastic in nature (for example, the probability of invasion) or uncertainties that stem from a lack of information, provided they can be described in terms of a probability distribution. In our case study, damage from invasive species is delimited to one enclosed geographical area. However, this assumption can be relaxed in further analysis. Grid-based, spatially explicit metapopulation models (e.g. Perry and Enright, 2007) would be ideal tools to account for a multitude of adjacent areas or patches at risk of invasion, but are probably too complicated to be linked with recursive optimization. There are also other, computationally less demanding approaches to account for spatiality. Bogich and Shea (2008) applied what they call a “moving window” approach to describe the spread of infestation across a finite number of patches and states, and successfully solved the adaptive, dynamic problem of managing destructive invasive forest pests. Kaiser and Burnett (2010) modeled the temporal and spatial spread of an invader using a Fisher–Skellam diffusion process, and managed to find optimal early detection and rapid response policies to manage the Brown tree snake (Boiga irregularis) populations in Oahu, Hawaii. Developing well-calibrated and validated models for the population dynamics of invasive species is challenging because, by definition, invasive species have not yet entered the focal area and local data is not available. This study, like all earlier numerical applications in this field (e.g. Leung et al., 2002), employs and combines empirical data and observations from various sources. It is likely that the central relationships and processes driving population dynamics, such as reproduction, mortality, and growth rate, do not differ between areas; however, there is no evidence regarding the intensity and speed of these processes in new areas, and the model parameters must thus be simply assumed based on environmental conditions there. We have used a cohort model that is flexible enough to accommodate any changes or improvements as new information about the type and intensity of growth and reproduction processes becomes available. As a more general conclusion, we may state that the results of this study emphasize the importance of identifying, quantifying and internalizing all major external costs in energy-related decision making (European Commission, 2003). Our case study illustrates a situation where installation of a new nuclear power plant causes additional potential external costs in the form of an increased risk of invasive species. The probability distribution of external costs provides valuable information and should be explicitly accounted for when considering alternative locations for a plant and also when weighing the advantages and disadvantages of different sources of energy. The risk of heat pollution in water discharge areas sustaining an invasive aquatic species reduces the competitiveness of nuclear power in comparison to other forms of energy. One may be tempted to play down the negative externalities of nuclear power by claiming that the potential changes to the adjacent ecosystems are temporary. The average lifetime of a nuclear power plant is 40–60 years. It might be assumed, for example, that after the plant is closed, the conditions in the heat pollution zone will return to normal and that any species that invaded the area will likely disappear as the living conditions become harsh again. However, there are several counterarguments. First, due to climate change, the climatic conditions on the northern shores of the Baltic Sea may become more favorable to an established population of Asian clams, allowing it to survive after plant closure. Moreover, the Asian clam population that invaded the heat pollution zone may change over time and be able to survive under harsher conditions. Second, an established population in the heat pollution zone may act as a gateway for secondary spread to new areas and pockets of shoreline with favorable conditions. The external costs of an invasion tend to increase with time and rate of expansion. The Asian clam survives well in fresh water (cf. Sousa, 2008), and the species may well spread to inland waters through the mouths of nearby rivers. It should be pointed out that the planned nuclear power plant is only about 10 km away from the mouth of the Kemijoki, Finland's longest river, whose catchment area covers most of northern Finland. Third, a large invasion of the Asian clam is likely to reduce and/or replace indigenous clam or mussel populations and may thus have severe, irreversible ecological impacts. A mere awareness of such risks may reduce the welfare of some citizens, even if they do not plan to use the ecosystem services provided in the area. Such additional costs attributed to alterations in non-market ecosystem services require increased management effort and create incentives for implementing existing and identifying new preventive measures.