دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 5590
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

افق برنامه ریزی تولید، هموارسازی تولید و تحدب توابع هزینه

عنوان انگلیسی
Production-planning horizon, production smoothing, and convexity of the cost functions
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
5590 2003 8 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : International Journal of Production Economics, Volumes 81–82, 11 January 2003, Pages 67–74

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
- تحدب - تابع هزینه - هموارسازی تولید -
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Convexity,Cost function,Production smoothing,
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  افق برنامه ریزی تولید، هموارسازی تولید و تحدب توابع هزینه

چکیده انگلیسی

One of the productions planning models economists have used for the past four decades is the production-smoothing model. The model's conclusion is simple: if cost functions are convex, under certain conditions, firm's production plans may show smaller variability than the firm's sales. This is a result of the first-order condition for cost minimization over the production-planning horizon. In a 1986 paper Blinder raised doubts regarding the ability of the production-smoothing model to explain the observed data. Some researchers (e.g. Ramey, Journal of Political Economy 99(2) (1991) 306) explained the inconsistency between the theory and the data by providing evidence that the cost functions are non-convex. In this paper, I point out that the shapes of the cost functions depend on the length of the time horizon under consideration. It is possible that while short-run cost functions are upward sloping, long-run cost functions may be downward sloping. Because the planning horizon for firms facing seasonal demand has been shown to be one seasonal cycle, the short-run cost function, whose shape determines the firm's production plan over the horizon, need to be estimated using single planning horizon data, i.e., a single seasonal cycle. Researchers who use long time series data are, in effect estimating long-run cost functions, the slopes of which may be non-positive. I show, further, that convexity of the production cost function is neither necessary nor sufficient condition for production smoothing to be an optimal plan.

مقدمه انگلیسی

One of the production-planning models economists have used for the past four decades is the production-smoothing model.1 The model's conclusion is simple: if cost functions are convex, under certain conditions, firm's production plans may show smaller variability than the firm's sales. This is a result of the first-order condition for cost minimization over the production-planning horizon. Starting with quadratic cost functions Ramey (1991) derives the Euler equation and interprets it as follows: “The first-order condition states that the firm equates the marginal gain from producing one unit today instead of tomorrow to the cost of holding the unit in inventory. The difference in costs between the two periods depends on production because marginal costs vary with the level of production” (Ramey, 1991, pp. 312–313). The production-smoothing model, in various formulations, has been empirically implemented and has received some support. In a study of monthly physical quantity data on six industries and monthly cross section data on one industry, Ghali (1974) reported strong support for the model. Fair (1989) using monthly physical quantity data on seven industries, reported results that are “quite supportive of the production-smoothing hypothesis” (1989, p. 368). Krane and Braun reported evidence of production smoothing in 25 out of the 38 four-digit industries they studied (1991, p. 569).2 Of the 13 cases in which the variance of production exceeded the variance of shipment nine were accounted for by “agricultural or lumber products and the materials inventory cases” (1991, p. 569). When Krane and Braun decomposed the variances of production and shipment into seasonal and residual components, they found production to be smoother than sales in 30 of the 38 series. As in Ghali (1974) and Fair (1989), Krane and Braun (1991) used monthly physical quantity data which had not been subjected to seasonal adjustment and which pertained to four-digit or higher SIC industries. However, the empirical support is not universal. In a 1986 paper Blinder raised doubts regarding the ability of the production-smoothing model to explain the observed data (Blinder, 1986). He examined data on ten durable goods and ten non-durable goods, two-digit manufacturing industries. He found that “…the production-smoothing model is in trouble. Certain overwhelming facts seem not only to defy explanation within the production-smoothing framework, but also actually to argue that the basic idea of production smoothing is all wrong. First, firms do not in fact smooth production; production is actually more variable than sales” (1986, p. 432). West (1986), Krane and Braun (1991), and Demelis and Ghali (1994) used a Generalized Variance Bounds test, rather than the simple variance ratio used by Blinder. These tests require the estimation of the parameters of the Euler equation derived from the minimization of quadratic cost functions. Krane and Braun (1991) while reporting the “detrended production is smoother than detrended shipments in 25 out of 38 industry or product groupings” also found that signs of the estimated parameters of the cost functions are “not consistent with those assumed by the production-smoothing versions of these models. Consequently, formal variance bounds tests do not yield much insight in tests of optimization models” (1991, p. 577). Ramey (1991) explained the inconsistency between the stylized and the observed facts by arguing that cost functions are non-convex. She used data for industries aggregated to the two-digit SIC level, and more disaggregated data on the automobile industry and the pneumatic casings industry to estimate the Euler equation. Reviewing her empirical results, Ramey concludes “The empirical results… cast serious doubt on the notion that firms use inventories to smooth production. The estimates from the stochastic Euler equation indicate that firms behave as if they faced declining, not rising marginal costs. Instead of smoothing production, firms seem to bunch production” (1991, p. 329). It is important to note that the shape of the production cost function, whether convex or non-convex, is an important determinant, but not the only determinant, of whether production smoothing is an optimal behavior.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

In the schematic representation below, we show that for only a subset of manufacturing industries we should expect to see production smoothing. This schematic representation also illustrates that it is not possible to infer non-convexity of production cost functions from the observation that some industries do not smooth production. In addition, the schematic representation makes it clear that comparing the number of industries in which the variance of sales exceeds the variance of production to the number in which the variance of production exceeds the variance of sales is not a viable test of the production-smoothing hypothesis. Unless one confines the analysis solely to data on industries for which the model should a priori be applicable, the percentage of cases where smoothing is observed is irrelevant. Indeed, should one find the model is empirically applicable to industries for which theoretically it should not apply, one must entertain serious doubts as to the value of the model (Fig. 1).