دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 8947
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

قوانین مالیاتی بهینه و بهره وری بخش دولتی با اثری جانبی در مدل نسل های همپوشانی

عنوان انگلیسی
Optimal tax rules and public sector efficiency with an externality in an overlapping generations model
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
8947 2010 13 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Journal of Public Economics, Volume 94, Issues 11–12, December 2010, Pages 1028–1040

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
اثر جانبی محیط زیست - قانون مالیات مطلوب - مالیات محیط زیست - دینامیک -
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Environmental externality,Optimal taxation rule,Environmental tax,Dynamics,
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  قوانین مالیاتی بهینه و بهره وری بخش دولتی با اثری جانبی در مدل نسل های همپوشانی

چکیده انگلیسی

This paper examines optimal tax rules and public sector efficiency, integrating them in a second-best world with pollution by using an overlapping generations model. The second-best world is characterized by the comparative statics of green preferences. The main results obtained are as follows. First, the marginal cost of public funds may be reduced by the externalities, regardless of the choice of taxes. Second, optimal environmental and non-environmental tax rules are additively and directly affected by the dynamic efficiency of capital accumulation per unit labour (DECAL), and indirectly by it, through the efficiency of the public sector. Environmental taxes going beyond Pigovian ones may be welfare-improving if the DECAL is improved by the environmental tax. Even optimal non-environmental tax rules should additively and directly counter the dynamics of pollution to consider the income effects of the optimal tax system for the future. Third, the “additivity property,” or the “principle of targeting,” does not hold even in the absence of incentive compatibility constraints. The essential reasons for this are clarified as follows: distortions that should be countered by taxes; that is, the income effects of the optimal tax system and the DECAL in this model, break the equality between optimal environmental taxes and the externalities measured by governments. Finally, growing environmental concerns may, in fact, increase pollution. The inverse relationship between environmental and labour income taxes may not hold.

مقدمه انگلیسی

This paper examines optimal tax rules and public sector efficiency, and integrates them in a second-best world with environmental externalities by using an overlapping generations model (OGM). The economy of the second-best world is characterized with the comparative statics of greater environmental concern, or greater green preferences. Environmental taxes are known as incentive-based environmental policy instruments. The double dividend hypothesis of environmental taxes suggests that environmental taxes can be useful instruments for not only environmental policies but also tax policies in financing public expenditure; that is, environmental taxes may not only improve the environment but also alleviate the inefficiency of distortionary taxes if revenues from the former taxes are used to reduce the latter taxes (see Tullock, 1967 and Pearce, 1991).1 Therefore, it is necessary to examine optimal tax rules in a second-best world with the externalities from various perspectives to obtain an approximate criterion for testing the optimality of environmental tax policies. The representative results concerning optimal environmental tax rules in a second-best world are provided by Sandmo, 1975, Bovenberg and de Mooij, 1994 and Bovenberg and van der Ploeg, 1994. These works conclude that optimal tax rules additively consist of distortions covered by taxes, and that a distortion should be directly countered by a tax that acts on the distortion. This is called the “additivity property” by Sandmo (1975) and the “principle of targeting” by Dixit (1985). Bovenberg and de Mooij (1994) find that environmental taxes falling below Pigovian ones are welfare-improving.2 Further, Bovenberg and van der Ploeg (1994) show that green preferences bring about a decline in employment, while they improve the environment, regardless of the labour supply curve.3 On the other hand, Cremer et al. (1998) show that the additivity property breaks down under incentive compatibility constraints owing to consumer heterogeneity, nonlinear income taxes, and public non-observability of the consumers' earning abilities. Moreover, Schöb (1997) mathematically indicates that non-environmental tax rules include externalities, but does not discuss the reasons for this and the economic implications. Schöb (1997) focuses on the normalization trap of taxes. Thus, these two studies do not clarify the essential reasons for and implications of the additivity property breaking down. The abovementioned papers discuss the additivity property with static models. Discussions on pollution should not overlook the important fact that pollution is accumulative, and its dynamic aspects. Accumulative pollution affects not only the present but also the future. Its effects differ across generations, whose life spans differ from the life span of an economy. These implications are emphasized by Solow, 1986 and Padilla, 2002. As Assouline and Fodha (2006) show, the double dividends of environmental taxes primarily depend on the dynamic efficiency of capital accumulation. Altonji et al. (1992) empirically reject the altruistic links of the distribution of income and consumption in infinitely lived agent models. Therefore, when analyzing optimal environmental tax rules in a second-best world, we need to consider the future effects of pollution and the differences in the life spans between an economy and consumers. In analyzing optimal tax rules, the efficiency of the public sector should be considered, since, as Pigou (1947) states, the efficiency of the public sector reflects that of the tax system. Atkinson and Stern (1974) show that the effect described by Pigou (1947) is indicative of the growth of the public sector. Atkinson and Stern, 1974, Batina, 1990 and Sandmo, 1998 examine the public sector in the absence of pollution. The main result of their studies is that whether the public sector grows or shrinks due to the distortionary nature of taxation depends on the marginal tax rate, or the choice of taxes and the income effects of taxed goods. Batina (1990) uses a Diamond OGM and shows that public sector efficiency depends not only on the marginal tax rate but also on the dynamic efficiency of capital accumulation per unit labour (DECAL). Batina discusses this in the context where the source for the DECAL is taxes on interest income, or the intertemporal allocation of a generation. Batina does not discuss all the sources for the DECAL, since it appears even without taxes on interest income. The efficiency of the public sector under pollution is discussed by Bovenberg and de Mooij, 1994 and Bovenberg and van der Ploeg, 1994. They show that the marginal cost of public funds (MCPF) depends only on labour income tax rates and the own-price elasticity of labour supply through the additivity property under certain utility functions. However, these studies do not elaborate on the relationship between the efficiency of the public sector, the effect described by Pigou (1947), and pollution. To incorporate the dynamic aspects of pollution and capital accumulation into the analyses of optimal environmental tax rules and public sector efficiency, we adopt a Diamond OGM under a system with environmental taxes and linear labour income taxes.4 The latter are either proportional or progressive taxes, and their adoption facilitates the model and enables the clarification of the additivity property. From the ensuing analysis, we obtain four main results. First, the externalities of pollution affect the efficiency of the public sector, regardless of the choice of taxes. This is because all available taxes should consider their effects on the externalities. By doing so, the public sector may optimally shrink, since the effect of the externalities may be opposite to the effect described by Pigou (1947). Moreover, it is shown that the inefficiency of intergenerations may result in the public sector shrinking optimally. Second, the dynamics of capital accumulation and pollution affect optimal tax rules. Optimal environmental and non-environmental tax rules are additively and directly affected by the DECAL, since governments should consider the DECAL with all available taxes. Intergenerational allocation is considered by additively and directly controlling the value of consumption by the old generation, by imposing taxes on their consumption. This results in different optimal environmental tax rules across generations. Owing to the effect of the DECAL on welfare, it is ambiguous whether optimal environmental taxes lie above or below the marginal external cost of pollution (MECP). This suggests that environmental taxes going beyond Pigovian ones may be welfare-improving if the DECAL is improved by those environmental taxes. Not only optimal environmental tax rules but also optimal non-environmental ones should additively and directly counter the dynamics of pollution for the future. This is because all available taxes should consider the effects of income transfer from the taxes, including the externalities. In addition, the DECAL and the externalities indirectly affect all optimal tax rules through the efficiency of the public sector. Third, the additivity property, or the principle of targeting, does not hold even without incentive compatibility constraints. This is evident in the appearance of externalities in optimal non-environmental tax rules. The essential reason for this is that all available taxes should consider the effects of the taxes that include the externalities. This depends on whether or not distortions hinder the equality between optimal environmental taxes and the MECP and which instruments counter the externalities. This is discussed by categorizing the additivity property into a “weak” and a “strong” additivity property. This discussion tells us whether or not non-environmental taxes should consider the externalities and under what conditions and with what instruments the externalities should be considered. This third result means that the results obtained by Bovenberg and de Mooij, 1994 and Bovenberg and van der Ploeg, 1994 on the MCPF do not generally hold even under certain utility functions. This is because the DECAL breaks such equality between optimal environmental taxes and the MECP measured by the government. We show that their prior results hold only with the additional assumption that dynamically efficient capital accumulation per unit labour is achieved. This indicates that the main cause for the additivity property breaking down in this model is the inefficiency of either intergenerational allocation or the intertemporal allocation of a generation. Finally, greater green preferences may aggravate pollution in an optimal tax system. This implies that neither of the two dividends of Bovenberg and van der Ploeg (1994) may be obtained. However, these dividends can be obtained under certain conditions. The inverse relationship between environmental and labour income taxes, which Bovenberg and van der Ploeg (1994) arrive at, does not hold. It is important that governments consider these conditions when undertaking activities to educate people on the environment. This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the model employed in this paper. Section 3 defines the market equilibrium. Section 4 analyzes the efficiency of the public sector and optimal tax rules, and integrates them in the second-best world. Section 5 performs the comparative statics of greater green preferences. Finally, Section 6 presents the conclusion.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

This paper analyzes optimal tax rules and public sector efficiency, and integrates them in the presence of pollution under a second-best world, using an OGM. The paper characterizes the economy of the second-best world with the comparative statics of greater green preferences. This paper obtains four main results. First, the public sector may shrink with any taxes, as long as the government considers the externalities. This is because a tax should consider its effect on goods with externalities. Second, optimal environmental and non-environmental tax rules should additively counter the DECAL and the MECP. From the effect of the DECAL, environmental taxes going beyond the MECP may be welfare-improving if the DECAL is improved by environmental tax reform under certain circumstances where the economy is far from an optimum. These provide an approximate criterion of decision making on the environmental tax policy. Third, from the second result, the additivity property does not hold even without incentive compatibility constraints. It depends on whether or not the optimal environmental taxes are equal to the MECP measured by governments and what instruments counter the externalities through income effects. This discussion tells us whether or not non-environmental taxes should consider the externalities, and under what conditions and with what instruments the externalities should be considered. Finally, greater green preferences may increase pollution in an optimal tax system. This implies that neither dividend of Bovenberg and van der Ploeg (1994) may be obtained. However, both dividends are obtained under certain conditions. These are important considerations when governments engage in spreading environmental awareness. The agenda for further research is as follows. An important concern pertains to the effect of incentive compatibility constraints under nonlinear taxes on the optimal tax rules of this model. Pirttilä and Tuomala, 2001 and Golosov et al., 2003 show that incentive compatibility constraints are one of the sources for the DECAL, in the contexts of a endogenous wage with a OGM and a wedge between the marginal utility of consumption and the expected marginal utility of investment with a Ramsey model, respectively. In other words, does the additivity property hold or not and is the public sector efficient or not under such a circumstance? Further, environmental concern differs across people and generations. If the political economy issues of greener preferences consider such concern, then environmental policy is affected by the equity of greener preferences and the burden of environmental policy. It is worth examining how these circumstances affect the results of this model.