مدل سازی هیث -جارو-مورتون طول عمر اوراق قرضه و به حداقل رساندن خطر پرتفوی های بیمه عمر
کد مقاله | سال انتشار | تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی |
---|---|---|
24236 | 2008 | 15 صفحه PDF |
Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)
Journal : Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, Volume 43, Issue 1, August 2008, Pages 41–55
چکیده انگلیسی
This paper has two parts. In the first, we apply the Heath–Jarrow–Morton (HJM) methodology to the modelling of longevity bond prices. The idea of using the HJM methodology is not new. We can cite Cairns et al. [Cairns A.J., Blake D., Dowd K, 2006. Pricing death: framework for the valuation and the securitization of mortality risk. Astin Bull., 36 (1), 79–120], Miltersen and Persson [Miltersen K.R., Persson S.A., 2005. Is mortality dead? Stochastic force of mortality determined by arbitrage? Working Paper, University of Bergen] and Bauer [Bauer D., 2006. An arbitrage-free family of longevity bonds. Working Paper, Ulm University]. Unfortunately, none of these papers properly defines the prices of the longevity bonds they are supposed to be studying. Accordingly, the main contribution of this section is to describe a coherent theoretical setting in which we can properly define these longevity bond prices. A second objective of this section is to describe a more realistic longevity bonds market model than in previous papers. In particular, we introduce an additional effect of the actual mortality on the longevity bond prices, that does not appear in the literature. We also study multiple term structures of longevity bonds instead of the usual single term structure. In this framework, we derive a no-arbitrage condition for the longevity bond financial market. We also discuss the links between such HJM based models and the intensity models for longevity bonds such as those of Dahl [Dahl M., 2004. Stochastic mortality in life insurance: Market reserves and mortality-linked insurance contracts, Insurance: Math. Econom. 35 (1) 113–136], Biffis [Biffis E., 2005. Affine processes for dynamic mortality and actuarial valuations. Insurance: Math. Econom. 37, 443–468], Luciano and Vigna [Luciano E. and Vigna E., 2005. Non mean reverting affine processes for stochastic mortality. ICER working paper], Schrager [Schrager D.F., 2006. Affine stochastic mortality. Insurance: Math. Econom. 38, 81–97] and Hainaut and Devolder [Hainaut D., Devolder P., 2007. Mortality modelling with Lévy processes. Insurance: Math. Econom. (in press)], and suggest the standard pricing formula of these intensity models could be extended to more general settings. In the second part of this paper, we study the asset allocation problem of pure endowment and annuity portfolios. In order to solve this problem, we study the “risk-minimizing” strategies of such portfolios, when some but not all longevity bonds are available for trading. In this way, we introduce different basis risks.
مقدمه انگلیسی
A zero-coupon longevity bond is a financial security whose single payout occurs at maturity and is equal to the value at this time, of a so-called survivor index. The value at any times tt, of a survivor index, is given by the proportion of people still alive at time tt in an initially given population. We can distinguish two broad approaches in the literature to the modelling of longevity bond prices. A first approach is known as the “intensity” approach. In a sense, it is the counterpart to the “short-rate” approach in the interest rate term structure literature. Typical examples of these intensity models are, to give a few examples, Biffis (2005), Dahl (2004), Luciano and Vigna (2005), Schrager (2006) and Hainaut and Devolder (in press). The second approach consists of adapting the Heath–Jarrow–Morton (HJM) (see Heath et al. (1992)) methodology to the modelling of longevity bond prices. Cairns et al. (2006) is, to our knowledge, the first paper to exploit this idea. These authors studied different specifications for the prices of longevity bonds. In particular, they described the term structure of longevity bond prices as the product of two independent HJM models, one related to the term structure of risk-free zero-coupon bonds and a second one related to the survival probabilities. Miltersen and Persson (2005) extended Blake et al.’s results by removing this independence. However, they assumed the payouts of their longevity bonds at maturity were defined on the survival of a single individual. Bauer (2006) introduced the fact that the actual payouts of the longevity bonds depend on the proportion of individuals alive in a given population, and not on a single individual. Unfortunately, none of these papers properly defines the prices of the longevity bonds they are supposed to study. See Barbarin (2007) for a detailed discussion of these papers. The trouble comes from the fact that they fail to take into account the effect of the actual mortality in the population on the prices of their longevity bonds. The first and, probably, the main goal of this paper is, accordingly, to describe a coherent theoretical setting in which we can rigorously apply the HJM methodology to the modelling of longevity bond prices. For this, it is necessary to introduce an explicit model of the (actual) number of deaths in a given population, through a more or less general (marked) point process. Modelling this mortality explicitly is fundamental to offering a coherent and rigorous definition of longevity bond prices. A second important objective of this paper is to describe a more realistic financial market. We extend the existing literature in various directions. Firstly, we take into account an additional effect of the actual mortality on the longevity bond prices. We can distinguish two main effects of this actual mortality. The first is a purely mechanical effect. If 5% of the population of the survivor index on which a longevity bond is defined dies, then, everything else being equal, the price of the longevity bond will also decline by 5%. This simple mechanical and proportional effect clearly appears, for example, in the pricing formula of longevity bonds in the intensity models. This first effect can obviously only depend on the actual mortality in the population of the survivor index on which the longevity bond is defined. However, there is also a possibly much more subtle second effect which has (to my knowledge) never been taken into account either in the intensity models or in the HJM models. We know from financial economic theory that the price at time tt of a longevity bond with maturity TT should depend on the survival probabilities up to time TT, possibly adjusted for the risk, in the population on which the survivor index is defined. A priori, there is no reason to believe these (risk-adjusted) survival probabilities might not also depend on the actual mortality in the population. Investors, if they are rational, should update their estimates of the survival probabilities (even under the real measure) if they observe a mortality which is not in line with their previous expectations. They could even modify their correction for risk if the actual mortality makes them think they are bearing more (or less) systematic risk than they previously thought. Unlike the first effect, this second effect does not necessarily depend only on the actual mortality in the survivor index on which the longevity bond is defined; it may also depend on the mortality in other parts of the population. To be more concrete, let us assume we have a longevity bond defined on 40-year-old individuals and assume the time to maturity is 20 years. The price of this bond should depend not only on the actual current mortality of 40-year-old individuals, but also on the actual current mortality of 45, 50, 55, etc.-year-old individuals, because investors can use this information to update their expected future survival probabilities of the current 40-year-old population. This second effect does not appear in the existing intensity models because these models assume, at least implicitly, the random times of death are conditionally independent with respect to a certain filtration (which does not include the actual mortality) and to the risk-adjusted measure (the risk-neutral martingale measure). To me, these assumptions are not obvious. Secondly, we simultaneously consider different survivor indices, each defined on a different age group of the overall population. We can thus define a longevity bond term structure on each of these indices. In other words, unlike the existing literature, we do not consider a single longevity bond term structure but multiple longevity bond term structures. This is a natural extension, since longevity bonds defined on several indices would allow the insurance companies and pension funds to better tailor their assets to their liabilities. As the longevity bonds market matures, more and more longevity bonds, defined on different survivor indices, will naturally be issued. Since each longevity bond depends on the actual mortality in the whole population, complex dependencies could appear between the prices of the different longevity bonds. In particular, it is interesting to study the conditions yielding the absence of arbitrage between the different longevity bond term structures. Finally, we extend the existing literature by allowing the different survivor indices to be heterogeneous. In the current “intensity” models, the survivor index is always defined on individuals of the same age and who are homogeneous (identical forces of mortality). We do not make these assumptions here. In particular, our survivor indices can be defined on individuals of different ages. As we said, it is very likely that longevity bonds defined on different survivor indices will be issued in the future, but the number of different survivor indices will probably remain relatively low. In order to cover a large proportion of the insured population with a limited number of indices, it might be interesting to simply define larger survivor indices. For example, one longevity bond could be defined on the population currently between 20 and 35 years old, another on the population currently between 35 and 45 years old, etc. Survivor indices could be defined on larger or smaller age groups according to the needs of the insurance companies or the pension funds. Obviously, the population of such survivor indices would be heterogeneous from the point of view of mortality. Our model allows such “heterogeneous” longevity bonds to be dealt with. The third aim is to study the asset allocation problem for portfolios of endowments and annuities. In particular, we choose to study the “risk-minimizing” strategies of these liabilities. This theory has already been applied with success to life insurance by Møller (2001), Riesner (2006) and Dahl and Møller (2006), for example. In particular, Dahl and Møller deal with the risk minimizing strategies of life insurance liabilities with longevity risk. However, these authors assume only risk-free zero-coupon bonds are available for trading. Our paper differs in that it allows for trading in longevity bonds. An important aspect of our paper is that we introduce different types of basis risks. Finally, as a by-product of the asset allocation problem, we also study the market values of portfolios of endowments and annuities when longevity bonds are traded in the financial market. In this situation, the market values of these liabilities can be directly inferred from the observable prices of the longevity bonds, without assuming the completeness of the financial market. This paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we study in detail how to apply the HJM framework to the modelling of longevity bond prices. More precisely, Section 2.1 introduces the theoretical setting on which our paper rests. In particular, we describe the random times of death in the population as a marked point process. The assumptions about the distribution of these random times are very weak. We only assume they cannot occur simultaneously and that the times of death are totally inaccessible stopping times. In particular, our model encompasses all the “intensity” models defined on a Brownian filtration, as in Dahl (2004), Biffis (2005), Dahl and Møller (2006), Luciano and Vigna (2005) and Schrager (2006). Notice it does not, however, encompass Hainaut and Devolder’s model (Hainaut and Devolder, in press), since this model is defined on a more general “Lévy” filtration. In Section 2.2, we define the survivor indices on which the longevity bonds will depend, and in Section 2.3, the prices of the risk-free zero-coupon bonds. For the sake of generality, we assume these prices can also depend on the development of the actual mortality in the overall population. In this way, we introduce another possible dependence between the risk-free zero-coupon bonds and the longevity bonds that does not appear in the existing literature. In Section 2.4, we define the longevity bond prices. We believe our definition is more coherent than the previous ones appearing in the literature. In particular, in order to introduce the second effect of the actual mortality on the longevity bond prices described above, we assume the forward rates of the longevity bonds depend on the actual mortality in the whole population. In Section 2.5, we then derive the no-arbitrage condition in this general financial market. As in the traditional HJM model, this no-arbitrage condition can be expressed as a constraint on the drift of the different forward rates. Since we are modelling multiple term structures, this condition ensures there is not only no arbitrage opportunity for each term structure but also between the different term structures. In Section 2.6, we give alternative representations of the zero-coupon bond prices and longevity bond prices. In this way, we make the connection between the HJM approach and the “intensity” approach for modelling the longevity bonds. The results suggest that the basic pricing formula of the “intensity” approach could be extended to more general intensity models. In Section 3, we consider the asset allocation problem for endowments and annuities portfolios using the risk minimization theory. We recall the main results of this theory in Section 3.1. In Section 3.2, we give the risk-minimizing strategies for a given insurance company’s portfolios whose policyholders represent only a fraction of the population on which a survivor index is defined and when some, but not all, the longevity bonds are traded. In this way, we introduce different basis risks. As a by-product of the risk-minimizing strategies, we also give in this section, the market values of these endowments and annuities portfolios when longevity bonds are traded.