دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 25900
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

یادگیری اجتماعی و ثبت نام شدگان بیمه سلامت: شواهدی از تعاونی های جدید طرح پزشکی در چین

عنوان انگلیسی
Social learning and health insurance enrollment: Evidence from China's New Cooperative Medical Scheme
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
25900 2014 17 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Volume 97, January 2014, Pages 84–102

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
مناطق روستایی چین - بیمه بهداشت - یادگیری اجتماعی - اثرات همکاران
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Rural China,Health insurance,Social learning,Peer effects
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  یادگیری اجتماعی و  ثبت نام شدگان بیمه سلامت: شواهدی از تعاونی های جدید طرح پزشکی در چین

چکیده انگلیسی

This paper examines the role of social learning in household enrollment decisions for the New Cooperative Medical Scheme (NCMS) in rural China by estimating a static game with incomplete information. Using a rich dataset from the China Health and Nutrition Survey, we find that a 10-percentage-point increase in the enrollment rate in a village increases one's take-up probability by 5 percentage points. Using multiple model specifications, we show that the estimated social effects are not driven by simultaneity or common unobserved factors but are consistent with the hypothesis of social learning. We also find that the importance of social effects decreases significantly with households’ familiarity with the NCMS as well as with the development of alternative information channels, which further ascertains that the primary mechanism for the social effects is social learning. The evidence suggests that healthier, wealthier, relatively well-educated, older Han male household heads tend to be opinion leaders.

مقدمه انگلیسی

One of the main obstacles to social program take-up is a lack of information about the program (Moffitt, 1983, Craig, 1991 and Currie, 2004). For instance, Aizer (2007) finds that information costs are an important contributor to the low take-up rate in the Medicaid program in the United States. This problem could be more serious in developing countries, as the official information transmission channels are typically inadequate. However, such informational barriers could be reduced if information were transmitted through social learning, which refers to any mechanism through which people learn information from others before making decisions (Bandura, 1977). It may take the form of direct communication with or observation of others (Bikhchandani et al., 1998). The main objective of this paper is to quantify the importance of social learning in household health insurance enrollment decisions by exploiting the unique opportunity of the recent establishment and expansion of the New Cooperative Medical Scheme (NCMS) in rural China since 2003, which is a voluntary public health insurance program for the rural population and is one of the pillars of China's social security system. In the context of the NCMS, social learning may play a significant role in enrollment decisions and it is worth investigating for four reasons. First, as the NCMS is implemented in rural China, issues related to information barriers could be more serious because of the low education level of the rural population,1 a poor official information sharing scheme and less transparent government policies. Second, the operation of the insurance market in general is still new and complex for most households in rural China. Information on the procedures, payoffs and costs associated with the NCMS per se is limited because it is a newly established program. Although local government officials have exerted considerable efforts such as an intensive advertising campaign and door-to-door appeals (Wu et al., 2006 and You and Kobayashi, 2009) to convey information to rural households, the details of the NCMS program are still difficult for rural households to understand. For example, Pan et al. (2009) find that approximately 78 percent of survey respondents were unfamiliar with the detailed NCMS regulations implemented in their counties. Third, some studies find that when the NCMS was introduced, people had low levels of trust in local governments and were skeptical about the promised benefits of the NCMS, as the local governments had consistently imposed a number of taxes and fees on them but misused those funds in the past (Yip and Hsiao, 2009 and Yi et al., 2011). This distrust, combined with the low education levels of the rural population and the complexity of the NCMS program, may substantially reduce the effectiveness of the official information campaign, and increase information barriers. Finally, during the implementation phase of the NCMS, the social norms regarding and perceptions of the program were still being formed. Households in rural China typically live in close-knit villages, where they can effectively communicate with others. An individual villager can learn additional useful information from the behavior of his co-villagers, who might have better knowledge of or experience with health insurance, through word-of-mouth communication or observational learning. Therefore, social interactions and information exchanges among peers could have a long-term equilibrium effect on the take-up rate of the NCMS, which may be above or below than the optimal level (Dahl et al., 2012). Relative to a growing body of literature studying different aspects of public insurance programs in China, such as design and implementation (Mao, 2005 and Brown et al., 2009), and impact evaluation (Wang et al., 2009, Wagstaff et al., 2009 and Lei and Lin, 2009), our study contributes to the literature by investigating the determinants of NCMS participation, with a particular focus on the role of social learning at the village level. Specifically, we aim to examine whether an individual's decision to enroll in the NCMS is affected by the decisions of his co-villagers due to the informational content embedded in such decisions, using data from the three most recent waves, 2004, 2006 and 2009, of the China Heath and Nutrition Survey (CHNS). Our paper also contributes to the growing body of empirical literature on the effect of social learning in numerous contexts (Manski, 2000), such as health insurance plan decisions (Sorensen, 2006), retirement savings decisions (Duflo and Saez, 2002 and Duflo and Saez, 2003), welfare participation (Bertrand et al., 2000 and Dahl et al., 2012), contraception decisions (Munshi and Myaux, 2006), and stock market participation (Hong et al., 2004). Our work is distinct from those listed above in the sense that during our 5-year data period, the NCMS passed through different stages, from inception to expansion and to full coverage, which allows us to investigate the social effects during different stages of the program. Our empirical strategy also differs from the current practice in the literature. It is well known that the social effect is difficult to identify due to the mixture of simultaneous causality among peers, unobserved common factors within the peer group and endogenous selection into peer group (Manski, 1993 and Manski, 2000). The existing literature generally adopts one of three approaches to overcome the identification problems. One is to use instrumental variables (e.g., Duflo and Saez, 2002 and Chen et al., 2010) to account for the endogeneity of peers’ decision. The second approach is to focus on a certain subsample and impose certain assumptions regarding the pattern of social learning to overcome the simultaneity problem. For example, Sorensen (2006) studies the social-learning effects on the employer-sponsored health plan choices of newly hired employees by assuming that their choices are influenced by the existing employees, but not vice versa. The third approach of studying the problem is to use a randomized experiment to generate exogenous changes in peer groups or exogenous variation in information exposure among peers (e.g., Duflo and Saez, 2003 and Cai et al., 2009). In this paper, we adopt a different approach to identify the effect of social learning using observational data. We model the NCMS participation process as a static game with incomplete information, in which households make NCMS enrollment decisions based on their own household-level characteristics (some of which are not observed by other households), village-level characteristics, and the enrollment decisions of other households in the same village. There are several reasons that this model is applicable to a social learning context. First, the benefits that a particular household can obtain from the NCMS crucially depend on the overall enrollment rate. Second, other households’ enrollment decisions may reveal useful information about an NCMS plan that a particular household does not have. Third, each household may possess some private information about their own benefits and costs associated with enrollment. Therefore, we assume that households in each village engage in an incomplete information game, and make enrollment decisions strategically.2 The structure and role of the village in rural China make the village a natural peer group (we will discuss this further in Section 2), which helps to avoid the issue of endogenous group membership. To account for the endogeneity of peer enrollment decisions due to simultaneity and time-invariant common unobservables, we follow Bajari et al. (2010) and apply a two-step approach with household-level fixed effects. This identification strategy requires appropriate exclusion restrictions that there exist covariates affecting the behavior of one particular villager but not other villagers. In our paper, we assume that the take-up decision of one household is influenced only by its own health conditions but not directly influenced by the health status of the co-villagers (we will discuss this identification condition in Section 3, and provide the justifications in Section 5). Our main finding is that a 10-percentage-point increase in the enrollment rate of other households in the same village increases one's own take-up probability by 5 percentage points. Taking advantage of the panel nature and the richness of the dataset, we conduct two robustness checks to show that the estimated peer effects are not driven by time-variant common unobserved factors at the village or county level, but are fully consistent with the hypothesis of social learning. It is found that the peer effects increase with spatial proximity among household heads. The pattern within subgroups of the villagers is that healthier, wealthier, relatively well-educated, and older Han male household heads tend to be opinion leaders in the village. Moreover, we use different model specifications to further ascertain that the most likely mechanism for the estimated social effect in NCMS enrollment decisions is information transmission via social learning, but not other plausible alternatives, e.g., the desire to conform to peers’ actions. We find that the importance of social effects decreases significantly with households’ familiarity with the NCMS as well as with the development of alternative information channels. These findings have important policy implications, since they suggest that low income families and families living in relatively poor villages are influenced by social effects to a greater extent. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 briefly describes the institutional background of the NCMS in China. Section 3 outlines our econometric model and the estimation strategy. Section 4 describes the data and main variables. Section 5 presents our empirical findings, and Section 6 discusses the policy implications of our results. Section 7 concludes.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

In this paper, we investigate the importance of social learning in household NCMS enrollment decisions in rural China by modeling households’ enrollment decisions as a static game of incomplete information. In our model, households make their enrollment decisions based on their characteristics (some of them are private information), village characteristics, as well as other households’ enrollment decisions. We find that the NCMS enrollment probability of an individual household would increase by 5 percentage points if the enrollment rate of other households in the same village were to increase by 10 percentage points. From a policy perspective, such peer effects are equivalent to a social multiplier effect of 1.9 at the village level, based on the computation method proposed by Glaeser et al. (2003). We discuss and clarify how the identification problems can be resolved in order to establish a causal relationship between social learning and household enrollment behavior. First, we employ the two-step approach proposed by Bajari et al. (2010), together with household-level fixed effects, to control for the endogeneity of the village-level peer enrollment rate. This estimation strategy draws on the growing literature on estimating static discrete-choice games in industrial organization in which one agent's payoff is affected by other agents’ decisions, and can deal with simultaneity and unobserved time-invariant heterogeneity. Moreover, two robustness checks help to rule out the potential confounding influence of time-varying common unobservables in our two-step estimations, and provide further support for the establishment of causal peer effects. Second, using the rich information in our dataset, we conduct several specification tests to show that the mechanism for social effects in NCMS enrollment is primarily social learning. Specifically, we show that the role of social effects are more salient when individuals are unfamiliar with NCMS, and their influence increases with close geographical proximity, which is fully consistent with the theory of social learning. Moreover, we also find that the importance of social learning from co-villagers decreases significantly with the development of alternative information channels. We add to the literature by providing empirical evidence for asymmetric peer effects in the setting of health insurance enrollment. We find that healthier, older, Han, male household heads with higher education and income levels tend to be opinion leaders; they have a significant influence on households with low socioeconomic status. This is consistent with the empirical finding in other contexts. For example, Nair et al. (2010) find that research-active physicians significantly influence the behavior of other physicians but not vice versa. Thus, our results suggest that targeting opinion leaders in rural villages with an information campaign may have economically significant social multiplier effects on social programs. As a related finding to the existence of opinion leaders, our evidence also suggests that low income families and families living in relatively poor villages were more influenced by social learning, which may have important implications for the implementation and the evaluation of social programs. Finally, our data allow us to investigate peer effects at different stages of the NCMS program: from inception, to expansion, and to full coverage. We find that the importance of the peer effects varies with the evolution of the program.