سرمایه انسانی، سرمایه های خانگی و بازده دارایی
کد مقاله | سال انتشار | تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی |
---|---|---|
18882 | 2014 | 12 صفحه PDF |
Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)
Journal : Journal of Banking & Finance, Volume 42, May 2014, Pages 11–22
چکیده انگلیسی
Sousa (2010a) shows that the residuals from the common trend among consumption, financial wealth, housing wealth and human capital, cday, can predict quarterly stock market returns better than cay from Lettau and Ludvigson (2001), which considers aggregate wealth instead. In this paper, we use a more appropriate proxy of human capital, which alleviates the potential correlation between the residuals and the regressors and makes the estimation more precise. In addition, we extend housing wealth to household capital by taking durable goods into consideration. The new predictor is proposed accordingly. Empirically, we find that our predictor is superior to the other alternatives.
مقدمه انگلیسی
The predictability of asset returns using macroeconomic variables is one of the most important research areas in finance. Many predictors have been intensively studied. More recently, a lot of economically motivated predictors have been proposed, for example, the ratio of housing wealth to human capital (Lustig and van Nieuwerburgh, 2005), the composition risk (Piazzesi et al., 2007 and Yogo, 2006), the trend deviation of the long-run relationship between nondurable consumption, non-asset income, wealth and the relative price of durables to nondurables (Fernandez-Corugedo et al., 2007), the residuals of the trend relationship between housing wealth and labor income (Sousa and wealth, 2010b), as well as the ratio of asset wealth to human capital (Sousa, 2012a, Sousa, 2012b and Sousa, 2012c). Of all the predictors in the literature, the transitory deviation from the common trend in consumption, asset wealth and human capital (Lettau and Ludvigson, 2001), cay, is one of the most successful. Economic intuition is that investors who want to smooth their consumption adjust their current consumption if they expect transitory movements in their asset wealth caused by variations in expected returns. When the expected return rises, a forward-looking investor increases his current consumption. Conversely, when the expected return declines, he decreases it. Sousa (2010a) argues that some components of asset wealth have different characteristics and that it is appropriate to disaggregate them from asset wealth. Using US and UK data, he shows that the residuals from the common trend among consumption, financial wealth, housing wealth and human capital, cday, can predict quarterly stock market returns better than cay proposed by Lettau and Ludvigson (2001). Moreover, Afonso and Sousa (2011) find that cay and cday are not market-restricted as they can also predict stock returns in other OECD countries. The construction of cay or cday involves human capital. Unobservable human capital plays important role in recent asset pricing models, for example, Julliard, 2004 and Wei, 2005. However, how to proxy it has not been paid enough attention. The first contribution of this paper is that we improve the prediction abilities of cay and cday by addressing this proxy issue properly. From a microeconomic perspective, economists have proposed variables such as labor inputs with various adjustments (Denison, 1967), adult literacy rates and school enrollment ratios (Azariadis and Drazen, 1990 and Romer, 1990), and, the most popular, average years of schooling (Islam, 1995, O’Neill, 1995 and Barro, 2001) to specify human capital stocks. From a macroeconomic perspective, human capital is usually defined as the present value of future labor income and is measured in the aggregate (Auerbach et al., 1992 and Auerbach et al., 1994). As Macklem (1997) mentions, the macro or aggregate approach has two important advantages: first, it facilitates our understanding of the joint statistical properties of shocks in income and interest rates; second, at the macro level, the data requirements are much less onerous, making this approach easily applicable to different countries. Both Lettau and Ludvigson, 2001 and Sousa, 2010a take the macro approach and substitute human capital (logarithmic value) with a linear function of current labor income (logarithmic value). Although this substitution is supported by economic theory and data, it is not appropriate to use it to construct cay or cday as both cay and cday are obtained using the “dynamic least squares” (DLS) regression proposed by Stock and Watson (1993). The DLS specification adds leads and lags of the first difference of the right-hand side variables to a standard “ordinary least squares” (OLS) regression to eliminate the effects of regressor endogeneity on the distribution of the least squares estimator. However, if human capital is substituted by a linear function of current labor income, it causes a correlation between the residuals of the regression and the leads and the lags of the first difference components. This correlation jeopardizes the good finite-sample properties of the DLS estimators. In order to eliminate it, we follow Macklem (1997) using a Markov chain to calculate the sum of the expected present value of labor incomes, and treat this as a proxy for human capital. This produces better estimators. The second contribution of this paper is a closer examination of the importance of wealth composition, as first emphasized by Sousa (2010a). Sousa (2010a) disaggregates aggregate wealth into financial wealth, human capital and housing wealth, and finds a superior predictor of financial asset returns over cay. Similar to housing wealth, durable goods (such as clothing and furniture) also have these special characteristics unlike financial wealth. They are different from financial wealth with respect to liquidity, utility from ownership rights, and the different distributions across income groups, among others. Many researchers have examined these differences, for instance, Hess, 1973, Mankiw, 1982, Grossman and Laroque, 1990, Caballero, 1993 and Hong, 1996. Moreover, the value of durable goods is increasing rapidly. Recently, it accounts for around 7% of aggregate wealth. Therefore, we define the sum of durable goods and housing wealth as household capital and disaggregate them from aggregate wealth. So, we use the expected present value of labor incomes as a proxy for human capital, and estimate the transitory deviation from the common trend in consumption, financial wealth, human capital and household capital. We define this transitory deviation as a new predictor, cadh. cadh should outperform cay and cday because the parameters are estimated more precisely and durable goods are taken into consideration in cointegrating. Empirically, we collect US quarterly data from 1952 to 2011, and split it into two subsamples. The first is from the first quarter of 1952 to the fourth quarter of 1976; the second is from the first quarter of 1977 to the fourth quarter of 2011. The reason for doing this is that the cointegrating vectors among consumption, financial wealth, human capital and household capital are different for these two subsamples. The difference of the cointegrating vectors reflects the change in the long-run elasticities of consumption with respect to financial wealth, household capital, and human capital. Specifically, the elasticities with respect to financial wealth and human capital increase and decrease respectively, while the elasticity with respect to household capital remains relatively unchanged. Finally, we compare the predictive power of cadh,caycadh,cay and cday. We find that in the first subsample, our predictor can explain at most 12% variation over the next 8 quarters for in-sample forecasting while cay and cday explain, at most, 7% and 9% variation, respectively. In the second subsample, the numbers increase to 31%, 26% and 27%, respectively. Moreover, we show that the superiority of our predictors is due to both good measure of human capital and usage of household capital. For out-of-sample forecasting, all three predictors improve the mean squared error (MSE) compared with the constant return model, and the improvements are significant. While, our predictor is the best in terms of MSE. The rest of this paper is organized as follows: Section 2 describes our estimation model; Section 3 reports the empirical analysis; and Section 4 concludes.
نتیجه گیری انگلیسی
In this paper, we improve the prediction power of cay in Lettau and Ludvigson (2001) and of cday in Sousa (2010a). Similar to these two papers, we use budget constraint to derive the cointegrating relationship between consumption and the different components of wealth, and then apply the trend deviation denoted by cadh to predict stock returns. Our predictor, cadh, has superior prediction power over cay and cday in two respects. First, as we use an appropriate proxy for human capital, we avoid potential endogeneity in the DLS regression. Specifically, we use a VAR (1) model to forecast the growth rate of labor income and discount rates, and we sum the current values of all future labor income. This sum is regarded as current human capital. Second, we further explore the importance of wealth composition. We generalize housing wealth as defined in Sousa (2010a) to be household capital, which includes both housing wealth and durable goods. This is because durable goods are quantitatively an important part of aggregate wealth, and they are similar to housing in terms of their liquidity, utility from ownership and income distribution. Empirically, we find that there is a structural change in the data between 1952–1976 and 1977–2011. First, the cointegrating vectors among consumption, financial wealth, household capital and human capital are different for each subsample. This difference reflects a change in the long-run elasticities of consumption with respect to financial wealth, household capital, and human capital, which is corroborated by a change in personal income compositions. Second, the relationship between the growth rates of household capital and consumption is different. In the first subsample, the growth rates of household capital are not significantly associated with the future growth rates of consumption. In the second subsample, the growth rates of household capital are significantly and positively related to the future growth rates of consumption. These two phenomena are consistent with the empirical literature studying the data before and after the mid-1970s. Sousa (2010a) verifies the growth rate relationship and attributes it to the persistence of household assets. We also observe that the growth rates of household capital have significant positive autocorrelation in the second subsample but not in the first one, interestingly consistent with the discussion of Sousa (2010a). There is currently no discussion of any such structural break in US data in the literature. We compare the in-sample and out-of-sample forecasting performances of our predictor, cadh, with cay and cday for the two subsamples. In both subsamples, cadh outperforms the other two. This supports the importance of our human capital proxy in the regression and durable goods in wealth composition. Moreover, the predictive abilities of the three predictors tend to be stronger post 1977. A possible explanation is that the Great Moderation made investors’ expectations more precise.