دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 26803
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

آیا بدهی نقدی منفی است؟ چشم انداز توقف در سیاست های مالی شرکت ها

عنوان انگلیسی
Is cash negative debt? A hedging perspective on corporate financial policies
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
26803 2007 40 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Journal of Financial Intermediation, Volume 16, Issue 4, October 2007, Pages 515–554

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
- مدیریت ریسک - اصطکاک های مالی - سرمایه گذاری - سیاست های نقدی - ظرفیت بدهی
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Risk management, Financing frictions, Investment,Cash policy, Debt capacity
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  آیا بدهی نقدی منفی است؟ چشم انداز توقف در سیاست های مالی شرکت ها

چکیده انگلیسی

We show theoretically that while cash allows financially constrained firms to hedge future investment against income shortfalls, reducing current debt is a more effective way to boost investment in future high cash flow states. Thus, constrained firms prefer higher cash to lower debt if their hedging needs are high, but lower debt to higher cash if their hedging needs are low. We provide empirical evidence that supports our theory. Our analysis points to an important hedging motive behind cash and debt management policies. It suggests that cash should not be viewed as negative debt in the presence of financing frictions.

مقدمه انگلیسی

Standard valuation models subtract the amount of cash in the firm's balance sheet from the value of outstanding debt in order to determine the firm's leverage. This practice reflects the view of cash as the “negative” of debt: because cash balances can be readily used to redeem debt (a senior claim), only net leverage should matter in gauging shareholders' residual wealth. The traditional valuation approach assumes that financing is frictionless and does not assign much of a relevant, independent role for cash holdings in the presence of debt obligations. In contrast to the traditional view, a number of recent studies show that corporate liquidity is empirically associated with variables ranging from firm value and business risk to the quality of laws protecting investors.1 These studies imply that cash holdings are a relevant component of the firm's financial structure. However, as pointed out by Opler et al. (1999), most of the variables that are empirically associated with high cash levels are also known to be associated with low debt. The findings that corporate cash holdings are related to variables such as value and risk—although relevant in their own right—cannot differentiate firms' policies regarding cash and debt. In effect, those findings cannot rule out the argument that firms regard cash as negative debt. This paper proposes a theory of cash–debt substitutability in the optimal financial policy of the firm. We start from the observation that while standard valuation models assume that financing is frictionless, there is ample evidence to suggest that raising funds in the capital markets can be rather costly. Information and contracting frictions often entail high deadweight costs to external financing. And exposure to those costs may affect the way firms conduct their financial and investment policies (e.g., Gomes and Phillips, 2005 and Rauh, 2006a), giving rise to a “hedging motive” (Froot et al., 1993). Building on this argument, we develop a theoretical framework in which cash and debt policies are jointly determined within the firm's intertemporal investment problem. Among the innovations of our theory, we explicitly identify when cash is not the same as negative debt. We also characterize circumstances under which cash and debt policies can be used as effective hedging tools. Our study presents novel empirical evidence on the interplay between corporate cash and debt policies, identifying a hedging motive behind financially constrained firms' cash and debt management Our model considers the process governing a firm's investment demand and the firm's ability to fund investment. We study a firm that has profitable investment opportunities in the future, but that faces limited access to external capital when funding those opportunities. Anticipating these constraints, the firm chooses its current financial policy so as to match up available funds to investment opportunities over time. To achieve this, the firm may boost its cash balances. The firm can do so by saving currently available internal funds or by issuing additional debt. Alternatively, the firm may save debt capacity by using current cash flows to reduce outstanding debt or by avoiding new debt issues. Higher cash stocks and higher debt capacity both increase the constrained firm's future funding capacity, hence the firm's ability to undertake new investment opportunities. Cash and (negative) debt can both be used to transfer resources across time. We show, however, that cash stocks and debt capacity are not equivalent when there is uncertainty about future cash flows. To understand the key intuition, consider a firm that issues risky debt against future cash flows. Because cash flows are risky, the current value of debt will be largely supported by future states of the world in which cash flows are high (the value of debt is higher in high cash flow states). By issuing risky debt today the firm transfers value from future states with high cash flows to the present. By subsequently saving the proceeds from the debt issuance (hoarding cash), the firm channels funds into all future states, including those in which cash flows and debt values are low. In other words, issuing risky debt and keeping the proceeds in the cash account is equivalent to transferring resources from future states with high cash flows into future states with low cash flows. On the flip side, saving/building debt capacity over time is equivalent to transferring resources into future states with high cash flows. In sum, constrained firms can manage their cash and debt balances so as to transfer resources across states in the future. Crucially, cash and (negative) debt perform different functions in the optimization of investment under uncertainty

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

We show that cash and negative debt can play distinct roles in the intertemporal optimization of investment by financially constrained firms. In essence, firms can use different combinations of cash and debt in order to transfer resources across future states of the world. These transfers allow constrained firms to improve the match between financing capacity and investment opportunities, and therefore can be value-enhancing. Empirically, we show that constrained firms with high hedging needs prefer to allocate excess cash flows into cash holdings. In contrast, constrained firms with low hedging needs use excess cash flows towards reducing outstanding debt. These observed empirical links between hedging needs and financial policies conform with the predictions of our theory. Our results suggest that there is an important hedging dimension to standard financial policies such as cash and debt in the presence of financing frictions. While the link between hedging and financing constraints was previously considered by Froot et al. (1993), the implications of this link for cash and debt had hitherto not been studied. In looking at cash and debt balances as hedging devices, we find evidence of activities by real-world firms that are consistent with the theoretical link between hedging and financing constraints. Such a match between theory and evidence has often eluded those researchers who focus on the use of derivatives as hedging tools. We also identify an empirical counterpart for the notion of hedging demand. Based on the correlation between firm-level cash flows and industry-level investment opportunities, our study suggests various easy-to-implement measures of hedging needs that future researchers may find useful (see, e.g., Rauh, 2006b). Our analysis focused mostly on the substitution effect between cash and debt among financially constrained firms. However, our empirical finding that financially unconstrained firms, too, display a systematic preference for using excess cash flows to reduce debt suggests that other considerations are also at play in the data. These considerations could include, for example, issues such as the yield on cash relative to the firm's effective borrowing cost and the diversion of free cash flows by management. Future research should try to identify the effects of tax parameters, agency problems, and liquidity premiums, among others, on the substitutability between cash and debt in financial policy-making. Finally, recent literature has shown the important role of lines of credit in managing liquidity needs. On the theoretical front, Holmstrom and Tirole (1998) focus on transfers of liquidity across firms and motivate the provision of lines of credit by financial intermediaries as a way of mitigating the adverse effects of systematic liquidity shocks. On the empirical front, Sufi (2006) shows that lines of credit are an important component of firms' overall financial policy and are employed for a wide variety of corporate finance purposes even by large firms in the US. Nevertheless, this literature has not embedded the dynamic management of cash and debt as a part of the firm's overall management of liquidity needs. In the context of our theory, lines of credit can be viewed as an effective way of transferring resources from today to low cash flow states in future.28 Crucially, however, Sufi (2006) documents that the ‘material adversity clause’ in lines of credit is invoked more often than assumed by the prior literature, denying liquidity to firms precisely when their need for liquidity may be high. This implies that there is a role for cash management even in the presence of lines of credit: cash balances transfer resources to future in an unconditional fashion, unlike lines of credit which may be subject to conditionality from material adversity clauses. We believe that integrating the roles of cash and debt management with the arrangement and usage of lines of credit is likely to be a rewarding direction for future research on financial constraints and hedging.