دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 8418
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

آیا قیمت های گزاف در بخش های سطحی می تواند باعث افزایش نوسانات نرخ ارز واقعی شود؟

عنوان انگلیسی
Do sticky prices increase real exchange rate volatility at the sector level
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
8418 2013 15 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : European Economic Review, Volume 62, August 2013, Pages 58–72

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
نرخ ارز و مستغلات - قانون یک قیمتی - قیمت های گزاف - آزمون یکنواختی ناپارامتری
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  آیا قیمت های گزاف در بخش های سطحی می تواند باعث افزایش نوسانات نرخ ارز واقعی شود؟

چکیده انگلیسی

We introduce the real exchange rate volatility curve as a useful device to understand the relationship between price stickiness and the fluctuations in Law of One Price deviations. In the presence of both nominal and real shocks, the theory predicts that the real exchange rate volatility curve is a U-shaped function of the degree of price stickiness. Using sector-level US–European real exchange rate data and frequency of price changes, we estimate the volatility curve and find the predominance of real effects over nominal effects. Good-by-good variance decompositions show that the relative contribution of nominal shocks is smaller at the sector level than what previous studies have found at the aggregate level, consistent with significant averaging out of good-specific real microeconomic shocks.

مقدمه انگلیسی

Among international macroeconomists, it is widely believed that the variability of real exchange rates is increasing in the degree of price rigidity. A reasoning is found in a prominent textbook by Dornbusch et al. (2004): “Exchange rate overshooting results from the rapid response of exchange rates to monetary policy and the sluggish adjustment of prices. A monetary expansion will lead to an immediate depreciation but only a gradual increase in prices. Exchange rate overshooting implies that real exchange rates are highly volatile (p. 534).” The basic idea is as follows. The nominal exchange rate is an asset price (since currencies are actively traded in the foreign exchange market) and thus it adjusts instantaneously in response to nominal shocks. However, if prices of many goods and services adjust sluggishly, the real exchange rate will be highly volatile because it comoves with the nominal exchange rate. The expectation, then, is a positive correlation between the volatility of real exchange rates and the degree of price stickiness if nominal shocks dominate the landscape, as they do in much theorizing on the topic. Quantitative investigations of this prediction have been undertaken, by Chari et al. (2002) who focus on the aggregate real exchange rates and by Kehoe and Midrigan (2007) who focus on Law of One Price (LOP) deviations. An early advocate for the role of real shocks in the equilibrium determination of real exchange rates is Stockman (1980). Stockman casts his model in a flexible price setting, so that nominal shocks make no contribution to real exchange rate volatility. Crucini et al. (2010), on the other hand, neutralize the effect of nominal shocks by focusing on intranational trade and investigate the role of real shocks on good-level real exchange rate volatility across cities in the presence of price rigidity. Unlike models emphasizing the role of the nominal shocks, their model predicts a negative correlation between price stickiness and real exchange rate variability because only real shocks affect real exchange rates across locations within a country. The current paper puts these two views of real exchange rate determination on the same playing field by combining the model of Kehoe and Midrigan (2007) which emphasizes nominal shocks with the model of Crucini et al. (2010) which emphasizes real shocks. These models rely on the time dependent pricing assumption, but allow the frequencies of price changes to vary across goods, as measured in the micro-data. Under the synthesized framework, we theoretically explore the cross-sectional relationship between price stickiness and real exchange rate volatility at the level of individual goods. We refer to this relationship as the real exchange rate volatility curve: the functional relationship between the forecast error variance of the real exchange rate and the infrequency of price changes at the level of a good. When real shocks are absent, the volatility curve is upward-sloping: an increasing function of the price stickiness parameter and the good with the stickiest price should exhibit the greatest amount of real exchange rate variability. When nominal shocks are turned off, the volatility curve is downward-sloping: a decreasing function of the price stickiness parameter and the good with the stickiest price has the least amount of real exchange rate variability. When both real and nominal shocks are present, the real exchange rate volatility curve becomes U-shaped. We estimate the volatility curve using sector-level real exchanges of Austria, Belgium, France, and Spain vis-à-vis the US, constructed by Kehoe and Midrigan (2007). We find that the estimated U-shaped curve is monotonically decreasing over the majority of the range of price stickiness. Our main findings regarding the shape of the curve are confirmed by both parametric and nonparametric estimation methods. The negative correlation together with the theoretical prediction of our model suggests the predominance of real shocks over nominal shocks in explaining the volatility of real exchange rates at the sector level. At the aggregate level, the relative contribution of real and nominal shocks to real exchange rate variability has been typically evaluated in terms of forecast error variance decompositions (e.g., Clarida and Galí, 1994, Eichenbaum and Evans, 1995 and Rogers, 1999).1 Following this literature, we further conduct variance decompositions of real exchange rates at the sector level, and evaluate the relative contribution of nominal and real shocks. For the majority of goods, the contribution of nominal shocks is smaller than that of real shocks, and real shocks rise in dominance as the forecast horizon lengthens. To reconcile our microeconomic evidence with the macroeconomic evidence, it seems necessary to allow for large idiosyncratic real shocks at the sector level such that these microeconomic sources of variation average out in the move to the CPI-based real exchange rate (Broda and Weinstein, 2008, Bergin et al., forthcoming and Crucini and Telmer, 2012).

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

We use a Calvo-type pricing model with real and nominal shocks to develop the concept of a real exchange rate volatility curve. The volatility curve has a U-shape as a function of the degree of price stickiness, implying an ambiguous correlation between the forecast error variance of real exchange rates and the degree of price stickiness. Using US–European real exchange rate data, the correlation was found to be negative over most of the range of observed degree of price stickiness. The downward-sloping profile suggested that for this micro-sample of goods and countries, real shocks account for most of the volatility of sectoral real exchange rates, though nominal shocks are important as well. The good with minimal real exchange rate volatility was estimated to have a duration between the price changes of about 4.8 months based on the benchmark quartic regression, and longer based on a nonparametric regression. However, to validate the generality of the theory, it is important to explore other samples of goods, cross-sections of countries and historical periods. Our results also point to the value of examining cross-sectional differences in real exchange rate variability in order to flesh out the rich quantitative predictions of models of micro-price adjustment currently under development. Differences across goods help us to disentangle heterogeneous responses to common shocks due to differences in economic propagation mechanisms such as costs of price adjustment and trade costs from heterogeneity in the underlying shocks themselves. Averaging across goods, as is inevitable in the move to an aggregate real exchange rate, is not innocuous in terms of the weight given to real and nominal shocks. The same averaging may also lead to an under-appreciation of the sources of the risks that individuals and firms face. We hope to explore these possibilities in future work. Much remains to be done.