دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 28444
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

توزیع منافع حاصل از سرریز از طریق تحرک کارگر بین کارگران و شرکت ها

عنوان انگلیسی
The distribution of the gains from spillovers through worker mobility between workers and firms
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
28444 2014 19 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : European Economic Review, Volume 70, October 2014, Pages 17–35

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
سرریز بهره وری - تحرک کارگری - دستمزدها - اطلاعات کارفرما - کارمند تطبیق
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Productivity spillovers, Worker mobility, Wages, Matched employer–employee data
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  توزیع منافع حاصل از سرریز از طریق تحرک کارگر بین کارگران و شرکت ها

چکیده انگلیسی

Knowledge spillovers through worker mobility between firms, found in previous research, imply that knowledge production within firms creates a positive externality to the hiring firms and their workers. We calculate the shares in the gains from spillovers retained by these parties using matched employer–employee data from Danish manufacturing. We find that around two-thirds of the total output gain (0.1% per year) is netted by the firms as extra profit, about a quarter goes to the incumbent workers as extra wages, while the workers who bring spillovers receive no more than 8% of it. This gains distribution, which favors the hiring firms, is similar for different types of moving workers, and is stable over time.

مقدمه انگلیسی

Theories of knowledge spillovers across firms have often relied on inter-firm worker mobility as a mechanism facilitating such spillovers (Fosfuri et al., 2001, Markusen, 2001, Glass and Saggi, 2002 and Dasgupta, 2012). Several recent empirical studies, including Gorg and Strobl (2005), Markusen and Trofimenko (2009), Balsvik (2011), Parrotta and Pozzoli (2012), and Stoyanov and Zubanov (2012), have documented the workings of this mechanism, linking firm productivity gains to hiring workers from technologically superior firms.1 Since the latter receive no compensation from the firms that hire their workers, the existence of knowledge spillovers through worker mobility implies a positive externality. The ambition of our study is to determine how much of this externality ends up as extra profit to the hiring firms, and how much is transferred as extra wages to the workers they employ. The findings from previous empirical studies, most of which focussed on the movements of workers from foreign- to domestic-owned firms, suggest that part of the ensuing output gains is indeed remitted to the workers. In particular, domestic firms pay a wage premium to new hires with foreign-firm experience over the wages of otherwise similar workers without such experience (Pesola, 2011). Incumbent workers benefit as well, seeing their wages grow in step with the share of ex-foreign firm employees in their firms (Poole, 2013). Hiring foreign specialists by domestic firms is also linked to wage increases in those firms, estimated at 4.5–6.2% depending on skill level (Markusen and Trofimenko, 2009). Despite the gains to the firms and to the workers being available from the above studies, there has been no attempt to compare those gains. Our study is the first such attempt. We estimate the gains from the worker mobility to the hiring firms and their workers using a specially designed empirical framework, and for all firms in an economy regardless of their domicile. Doing so requires a measure of a receiving firm׳s exposure to spillovers through worker mobility that is more flexible than foreign vs. domestic ownership of the sending firm. The lack of such measure in the previous literature forced researchers to narrow down the study scope, to assume that all foreign-owned firms are equally good sources of knowledge spillovers, and to ignore domestic firms as a source of potentially useful knowledge. Our method, which we outline below, relaxes these limitations. We estimate output gains from worker mobility and their distribution between the parties by tracking inter-firm movements of spillover potentials (SPs), whom we identify as the workers with a positive gap between their previous and new firms׳ total factor productivity (TFP) levels. This characterization is consistent with the theories behind spillovers through worker mobility (for example, Dasgupta, 2012) that treat the exposure to superior knowledge, which is manifested in higher productivity, as the source of spillovers. Assuming that output gains through mobility come entirely from SPs׳ higher labor productivity, aided by their exposure to knowledge in their previous firms, we obtain an equation linking a hiring firm׳s output gains from SPs to their average productivity gap and share in the labor force. We next derive a decomposition of the total output gains into the wage gains to SPs and non-SPs, and the profit gains to the hiring firms, which we estimate using linked worker-firm data from the Danish manufacturing sector. To preview our findings, the total output gain linked to SPs is 0.1% in the year after hiring, or just under a tenth of the annual productivity growth averaged over the sample period. Compared to otherwise similar non-SPs, SPs receive a wage premium of 1.17% per year on average. Non-SPs benefit too, though their average wage gain is a lot less, 0.09% per year. With SPs making up only about 2% of all the workers, the total wage gain from spillovers through mobility is 0.11% per year. Applying our gains decomposition to the above estimates, we calculate that the hiring firms net 57–76%, and non-SPs between 20% and 35%, of the total output gain, whereas SPs retain at most 8%. Put differently, firms receive a profit of around two dollars per each dollar spent on hiring SPs. This distribution of the output gains between the parties, which reveals abnormally high rents to the firms, is robust to alternative estimation approaches and is stable over time. On the qualitative side, our findings suggest that knowledge acquisition through hiring SPs may be a lucrative alternative to buying patents or in-house R&D, and is all the more attractive because it does not require significant cash outlays or technical expertise. It is, however, hard to pinpoint labor market imperfections that would explain the high rents to the hiring firms that we find. The one that we find most plausible and consistent with the (limited) empirical evidence so far is poor observability of moving workers׳ spillover potential, which leads to a lack of competitive market for SPs. Further research should examine this explanation more rigorously. In the remainder of this paper, Section 2 presents the conceptual framework for our study, which is followed by a discussion of the relevant estimation issues in Section 3. Section 4 presents our data together with some descriptive statistics. The baseline results – output and wage gains from SPs, and their distribution – are reported in Section 5. Section 6 contains a number of extensions corroborating our baseline results, and Section 7 concludes.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

The key question in our study has been to determine the distribution of output gains linked to spillovers through workers mobility between the hiring firms, the SPs, and the rest of the workers. We have found that the total output gain from SPs is 0.1% per year, of which the lion׳s share – at least two-thirds – is retained by the hiring firms, whereas the SPs themselves receive a paltry 8% at most. This finding implies that by far the biggest share of the positive externality from knowledge production enabled by the movement of workers between firms is retained by the hiring firms. Thus, to the extent that knowledge spillovers are important for economic growth, and inasmuch as worker mobility is a mechanism facilitating these spillovers, hiring new workers is instrumental for firms to gain cheap access to superior knowledge developed elsewhere. We believe that ours is the first study to show how output gains from knowledge spillovers through mobility are distributed between all the three parties involved. Another contribution to the relevant literatures is the unified empirical framework we have developed to measure spillovers through mobility, which can be applied to worker movements between any pair of firms regardless of their domicile. One useful feature of our framework, other than its generality, is that it is rich enough to support various extensions of our main research question, some of which we have implemented.