دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 3804
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

ساعت کار و استخدام

عنوان انگلیسی
Employment and hours of work
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
3804 2011 17 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : European Economic Review, Volume 55, Issue 2, February 2011, Pages 176–192

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
- استخدام - ساعات کار - اصطکاک جستجو
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  ساعت کار و استخدام

چکیده انگلیسی

This paper develops a dynamic model of the labor market in which the degree of substitution between employment and hours of work is determined as part of a search equilibrium. Each firm chooses its demand for working hours and number of vacancies, and the earnings profile is determined by Nash bargaining. The earnings profile is generally nonlinear in hours of work, and defines the trade-off between employment and hours of work. Concave production technology induces firms to overemploy and, as a result, hours of work are below their optimal level. The Hosios condition is not sufficient for efficiency. When there are two industries, workers employed by firms with higher recruitment costs work longer and earn more. That is, “good jobs” require longer hours of work. Interestingly, technology differentials cannot account for working hours differentials.

مقدمه انگلیسی

There are extensive and intensive margins for adjusting labor input: the number of workers and hours of work per employee. Understanding how firms utilize these two margins is crucial for understanding the long-run trend in hours of work (Prescott, 2004, Rogerson, 2006 and Pissarides, 2007), the movements of employment and hours over the business cycle (Burnside et al., 1993), the likely effect of regulation of hours of work (Hoel, 1986, Booth and Schiantarelli, 1987, Hunt, 1998 and Marimon and Zilibotti, 2000), and cross-sectional differences in hours of work (Hamermesh, 1993), to name a few. Recent decades have witnessed declines in hours of work in major developed economies (Rogerson, 2006 and Pissarides, 2007). Despite a decline in average working hours, disparities in working hours among workers have gradually increased. This disparity is particularly apparent for workers in their 30s. The Japanese Labour Force Survey (2006) documented that the proportion of male employees aged between 35 and 39 years who work more than 60 h per week rose from 18.9% in 1993 to 23.5% in 2003.1 Similarly, the proportion of those who work less than 35 h per week also rose from 6.4% to 7.1%. An important question is, what is the major cause of the dispersion in hours of work? In this paper, we construct a dynamic equilibrium model of labor demand under search frictions and focus on how firms utilize employment and hours of work. The idea is that hours of work can be chosen instantly whereas employment adjustment is frictional. A novel feature of this paper is that the source of labor adjustment costs is search frictions, and that the cost of adjustment is influenced by labor market tightness. Thus, the degree of substitution between employment and hours of work is determined as part of the search equilibrium. This sharply contrasts with traditional models of working hours ( Hoel, 1986, Booth and Schiantarelli, 1987, Calmfors and Hoel, 1988 and Cahuc and Zylberberg, 2004) and adjustment cost models ( Sargent, 1978 and Hamermesh, 1993), in which the degree of substitution between working hours and employment is structurally given by the production function or by the adjustment cost function. To understand the role of search frictions, consider the standard neoclassical model (Lucas and Rapping, 1969 and Prescott, 2004), in which workers face a labor–leisure choice and choose hours of work optimally, taking the market wage rate as given. In the neoclassical framework, firms can employ any quantity of labor at the market wage rate. Thus, from the firm's viewpoint, it does not matter whether workers work longer or shorter hours because the competitive market ensures that the quantity of labor demanded equals the quantity of labor supplied. On the other hand, with search frictions and bilateral trading, if employees work shorter hours, then the firm must pay extra search costs to maintain its labor input. Thus, firms do care about working hours. The basic model is an extension of Smith (1999), which is particularly useful for our purpose because the number of workers in each firm is determined endogenously, although modeling firm size in a search equilibrium is generally a formidable task.2 We incorporate the choice of working hours into Smith's (1999) framework. Each firm chooses the number of vacancies and hours of work per employee to maximize the value of the firm. A novel feature of the model of this paper is that Nash bargaining determines the earnings profile, which relates earnings and hours of work. In particular, the earnings profile is shown to be a nonlinear function of hours of work, which reflects the concave production technology and workers’ convex utility costs of longer hours of work. Interestingly, the earnings profile is consistent with the standard upward-sloping labor supply curve, and it defines the trade-off the firm faces when choosing employment and hours of work. Smith's (1999) main result is that firms overemploy. The mechanism is intuitive. The social planner does not take into account the wage rate when choosing the optimal employment level because wages are simply transfers among the members of society. However, firms do care about the wage rate. When the production technology is concave, an increase in employment results in a reduction in the wage rate. Firms have incentives to exploit this opportunity, resulting in overemployment. This mechanism also operates in our framework. The overemployment effect has an important implication for the efficiency of hours of work. Since the level of employment is too high, the marginal product of an additional hour of work is inefficiently low. This leads to shorter hours of work. We show that in the absence of the overemployment effect, employment and hours of work are efficient. An important finding is that, because of the overemployment effect, the Hosios (1990) condition is not sufficient for efficiency. To restore efficiency under concave production technology, we need to impose in addition that the firm appropriates all the bargaining surplus. In this case, the overemployment effect is internalized because the firm faces all the costs and benefits of choosing employment and hours of work. It has become increasingly important to ask whether regulating hours of work to implement some form of “work sharing” increases employment (Hoel, 1986, Booth and Schiantarelli, 1987, Hunt, 1998 and Marimon and Zilibotti, 2000). According to our model, under the regulation of working hours, a reduction in hours of work generally increases employment at each firm. Whether it expands aggregate employment depends on whether the marginal product of labor exceeds the marginal disutility of work. However, the laissez-faire level of hours of work is below its optimum, suggesting that implementing work sharing may expand employment at the cost of efficiency. We also study two other forms of regulation. One is wage regulation. We consider a scenario in which the earnings profile is perfectly regulated, and find that an earnings profile that mimics the worker's disutility function induces the efficient levels of employment and hours of work. The key requirement is to match the marginal hourly wage rate to the marginal disutility of longer hours of work. The other regulation we consider is entry regulation. Recently, this issue has become increasingly important (Bertrand and Kramarz, 2002, Blanchard and Giavazzi, 2003 and Fang and Rogerson, 2007). We consider a scenario in which the number of firms is regulated. We find that regulation that reduces the number of firms lowers hours of work and increases the number of employees at each firm. However, it results in higher unemployment because there are fewer firms. Interestingly, this result is overturned if a regulation takes the form of imposing a fixed cost of entry. This suggests that the details of implementing entry regulation matter. Hamermesh (1993) documented that there are sizable differences in working hours across industries. For example, in 1990 in the US, weekly hours of work averaged 44 in mining, 40.8 in manufacturing, 32.6 in services, and 28.8 in retail trade. This finding is interesting because it suggests that there are large differences in working hours among industries, each of which provides a variety of jobs. We extend the basic model to investigate why some individuals work longer than others. In doing so, we focus on job characteristics rather than worker characteristics as determinants of differences in hours of work. We first address within-industry differentials in hours of work, such as full-time–part-time differentials. To explain these differentials, we develop a model of a single industry in which the labor market is pooled for two types of jobs. The key determinant of differentials in working hours is differences in recruitment costs. For example, Hamermesh (1993) documented that firms incur much higher costs in recruiting workers with skills and education than in filling jobs that require little skill or training. Our result implies that jobs with high recruitment costs are characterized as “good jobs” (Acemoglu, 2001), and that workers with such jobs work longer hours than so workers with “bad jobs”. We also address interindustry differentials in hours of work. We develop a model that incorporates two industries in which labor markets are segmented. Because workers apply for work in one of the industries, there is arbitrage between the two markets. We show that the industry with higher recruitment costs pays higher wages and requires longer hours of work. The jobs in this industry are considered as “good jobs”, and the labor market tightness in this industry is lower because more workers apply for jobs in this industry. The key finding is that recruitment costs account for interindustry dispersion in hours of work. Interestingly, we find that differences in technology cannot explain working hours differentials.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

In this paper, we analyzed the choice of employment and hours of work in a dynamic model with search frictions and bargaining. We showed that the bargaining outcome defines the earnings profile faced by the firm when it chooses its composition of employment and hours of work. We found that differences in recruitment costs are responsible for dispersion in hours of work, both within and across industries. In particular, “good jobs” (Acemoglu, 2001) pay better and require longer hours of work. Interestingly, technology differentials cannot account for working hours differentials. An advantage of our approach is that the earnings profile is derived as part of an equilibrium. Since the earnings profile reflects both the production technology and the worker's disutility from labor, hours of work may be determined either by the firm's value maximization or by a worker's labor-leisure choice. In addition, the derived earnings profile is consistent with the empirical labor supply curve. We found that, because of Smith's (1999) overemployment effect, hours of work are below their optimal level. Further, the Hosios condition is not sufficient for restoring efficiency. To restore efficiency under concave production technology, the firm must appropriate the whole bargaining surplus. This is a general feature of large firm models with search and bargaining. Investigation of the robustness of this inefficiency result in richer environments belongs to future search. A limitation of our approach is that the basic model with free entry cannot support an equilibrium with heterogeneous firms. We modified the basic model by replacing the free entry assumption with endogenous entry. Generally, one needs a richer model of multiple industries to account for the heterogeneity of job characteristics in equilibrium, and much of this line of research is left for future research. A possible direction is suggested by Cahuc et al. (2008). In this paper, we did not consider the heterogeneity of workers. Kuhn and Lozano (2005) documented that the observed increase in hours of work in the US was concentrated among skilled men. A deeper understanding of dispersion in hours of work requires a model that incorporates heterogeneous skills. It would be interesting to incorporate skilled and unskilled workers into the model of this paper to investigate whether it can explain Kuhn and Lozano's (2005) findings. In this paper, we focused on the steady state. However, the choice of employment and hours of work is particularly important for understanding business cycles. It is well documented that during a recession, firms cut employment rather than reduce hours of work sufficiently to maintain the level of employment. Since employment adjustment is costly, it seems rational to hoard labor during a recession if favorable business conditions return shortly (Burnside et al., 1993 and Bertola and Caballero, 1994). This suggests that firms that fire their employees face large and persistent negative shocks during a recession. A useful task for future work is to extend the model of this paper to explain the substitution between employment and hours of work over the business cycle.