دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 9081
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

اثرات واقعی از سقوط رژیم نرخ ارز: یک برنامه کاربردی برای مکزیک

عنوان انگلیسی
Real effects of collapsing exchange rate regimes: an application to Mexico
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
9081 2002 27 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Journal of International Economics, Volume 57, Issue 2, August 2002, Pages 299–325

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
- سقوط رژیم نرخ ارز - تنوع خروجی - جریان سرمایه
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  اثرات واقعی از سقوط رژیم نرخ ارز: یک برنامه کاربردی برای مکزیک

چکیده انگلیسی

This paper examines the impact of collapsing fixed, permanently fixed, and flexible exchange rate regimes on real output. Much of the recent discussion of the causes of exchange rate regime collapses has focused on capital flows and export demands. In an environment in which such external shocks predominate, a flexible exchange rate is shown theoretically to produce lower output variability for a range of parameter values. A counterfactual exercise is performed using Mexican data. We find that had Mexico been on a flexible rate for the past two decades, the variance of real output would have been reduced by half.

مقدمه انگلیسی

The recent rash of currency crises and fixed exchange rate collapses in Latin America and East Asia provides ample evidence that in a world of liberalised financial flows, small transactions costs and large pools of mobile capital, the typical fixed or pegged exchange rate regime is extremely difficult to sustain.1 These crises have had significant real costs in terms of lost output and employment because of tighter monetary and fiscal policies and because of widespread financial distress due to the halt in capital inflows and higher debt payments.2 Our primary purpose in this paper is to investigate the impact of collapsing fixed exchange rate regimes on the variability of output. In addition, we examine the crucial policy decision facing emerging-market countries which are vulnerable to such crises: namely choosing an alternative exchange rate regime to avoid such disruptions in the future.3 Currency boards or common currencies are often put forward as appropriate alternative regimes (for example, Argentina and the European Union). We, however, demonstrate theoretically and empirically that these countries should instead look to the opposite end of the exchange rate spectrum and adopt a flexible exchange rate because it would provide greater macroeconomic stability in the face of capital flow and export demand shocks, especially if the fixed exchange rate regime has a nonzero probability of collapse.4 To illustrate this argument, consider Mexico’s recent experience. Over the last twenty-five years, it has had a series of controlled—fixed, crawling peg, dual and target zone—exchange rate regimes, all of which ended in crises and collapses.5 Each of the major crises over this period—August 1976, February and March 1982, July to November 1985, November 1987 and December 1994—was followed by a significant decline in economic growth (see Fig. 6). Although the factors responsible for these collapses have been described in detail elsewhere, it is important to note that external shocks to goods and asset markets in the form of oil price changes, capital flow shifts or interest rate changes played key roles.6 In particular, the typical boom and bust cycle in Mexico over this period began with a favorable external shock: for example, an increase in oil exports (following a discovery or an oil price increase), a fall in world interest rates or a liberalization of trade or capital flows. This shock was normally followed by large capital inflows, increased fiscal expenditures (typically deficit financed), an expansion of the domestic money supply, higher inflation and an appreciation of the real exchange rate. However, this process eventually became unsustainable, especially if the initial favorable shock was reversed or another adverse shock struck. A smooth adjustment of the real exchange rate, however, was precluded by the government’s commitment to the controlled nominal exchange rate, and the downward stickiness of prices and wages. Instead, the economy was stuck with an overvalued real rate, which generated the expectation of a future devaluation and consequent increase in the price of foreign goods. This, in turn, fueled an import boom and a flight of capital that reduced the foreign reserves of the central bank and eventually precipitated the collapse. Had the government, instead, adopted a flexible exchange rate, the favorable external shock and the resulting capital inflows would have appreciated the exchange rate, thereby reducing aggregate demand and the incentive to borrow. Similarly, when circumstances reversed, a depreciation would have occurred, thus avoiding the severe contractionary effects of an exchange rate collapse. The rest of the paper is divided into two parts. First, a theoretical model is derived under assumptions appropriate for countries like Mexico that have experienced such crises. Using the model, we show that in terms of minimizing the variability of real output, a flexible exchange rate regime generally dominates a fixed exchange rate that may collapse, as well as a permanent fixed regime (like a currency board). In the second part, a counterfactual empirical exercise is performed using data for Mexico that indicates that had Mexico adopted a flexible rate over the last 20 years rather than a series of controlled exchange rate regimes, the volatility of real output would have been substantially less.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

Our theoretical model demonstrates that for an economy facing capital flow and export demand shocks, the variability of output will generally be less under a flexible exchange rate regime than under a collapsing fixed exchange rate regime and in most circumstances under a permanent fixed exchange rate regime.29 The empirical counterfactual exercise on Mexico for the period 1973 to 1995 provides strong support for the hypothesis of the theoretical model that the conditional variance of output should be less under a flexible exchange rate regime rather than under a collapsing fixed or controlled exchange rate regime. Using a two equation (output, real exchange rate) VAR model, we find that the variance of output would have reduced by roughly half had Mexico been on a floating rate. Consistent with this result is the assessment of Werner (1998) who finds that Mexico’s flexible rate has performed reasonably well since the crisis of 1994. In particular, he argues that one of the benefits of a flexible exchange rate is that it absolves the government from making a political commitment to maintain the fixed rate and instead forces the private sector to either bear or hedge the exchange rate risk inherent in longer term international transactions. Although the trend for most developing countries appears to be toward more flexible exchange rates (Collins, 1996; Caramazza and Aziz, 1997), it is unfortunate that many countries make the switch too late, after a crisis and collapse have forced their hands. Indeed, the lesson that should be learned from these very costly mistakes is that a flexible exchange rate should be adopted when export demand and capital inflows are strong and the economy is performing relatively well, not the other way around.