This paper starts with a recapitulation of how emissions trading became a cornerstone of the European Union’s climate policy. While a whole bouquet of reasons can be identified the major reasons why the EU Commission decided to pursue the establishment of an emissions trading scheme within the EU are: (1) the integration of international emissions trading into the Kyoto Protocol; (2) the failure of the 6th Conference of the Parties to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) and the withdrawal of the United States from the Kyoto Protocol negotiations; and (3) the unsuccessful attempt to introduce an EU-wide CO2-tax. Other reasons were the fact that emissions trading did not need unanimity in the European Council like the CO2-tax; the economic efficiency of emissions trading which appealed not only to the Commission but also to industry and Member States; the danger of a fragmented carbon market as the United Kingdom and Denmark had already set up domestic emissions trading schemes that were incompatible; the incentive a European emissions trading scheme would be for the formation of a global carbon market; and the possibility to influence investment strategies of power companies towards a sustainable modernisation of the EU’s power generation infrastructure.
Drawing upon these preconditions, this paper analyses the development of the European Union Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS). Based on the fact that the EU is embedded in a multi-level policy-making architecture which encourages the emergence of policy networks it is argued that the EU ETS has been shaped by an (informal) issue-specific policy network established by some staff members from DG Environment, including individuals knowledgeable on emissions trading – such as experts from consultancies, environmental NGOs and the business sector. It is argued that within this European policy network on emissions trading the European Emissions Trading Directive – as adopted on 13 October 2003 – has been negotiated and developed. It is concluded that the sharing of knowledge about this relatively new and largely unknown regulatory instrument and about design options for a potential European emissions trading scheme was the key momentum for the establishment and continuity of this policy network and that the ability of managing knowledge generation processes was the main factor to allow for a few staff members from DG Environment to play a dominant role as policy entrepreneurs in developing the European Emissions Trading Directive, even beyond their formal role of proposing the scheme as representatives from the EU Commission.
When in 1968 Canadian economist John H.
Dales published his book
Pollution Property and
Prices
(
Dales, 1968
), he might not have guessed
the importance of his idea of emissions trading for
today’s climate policy. But since then, his idea has
come a long way and the trading of greenhouse
gas emissions has become a key policy instrument
to tackle the problem of global climate change. On
a global level, emissions trading
between govern-
ments
has been established as one of three flexible
mechanisms in the framework of the Kyoto Proto-
col. On the national level, many industrialised coun-
tries – ratifiers as well as non-ratifiers of the Kyoto
Protocol – have either introduced or are considering
company-based
emissions trading systems (cf.
Schu
̈
le
& Sterk, 2008; Sterk, Braun, Haug, Korytarova, &
Scholten, 2006
). And on the supranational level,
the European Union established today’s largest
company-based greenhouse gas emissions trading
scheme operating since January 2005. It encom-
passes about 11,500 installations from all its Mem-
ber States, responsible for around a third of the
EU’s greenhouse gas emissions, and roughly 45%
of the EU’s CO
2
emissions (
Vis, 2006, p. 48
).
In order to reach the Community’s emissions
reduction commitment of minus 8% compared to
1990 agreed to in the Kyoto Protocol the European
Commission proposed the establishment of a Euro-
pean Union Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS)
in the framework of its Post-Kyoto Strategy in June
1998 (
European Commission, 1998
). The proposal
was followed by a Green Paper in March 2000
(
European Commission, 2000
), a draft directive of
the European Commission in October 2001 (
Euro-
pean Commission, 2001a
), and a binding EU frame-
work directive – the European Emissions Trading
Directive – on 13 October 2003 (
European Commis-
sion, 2003a
). After having been implemented by all
EU Member States, the EU ETS finally went into
effect on 1 January 2005 encompassing CO
2
emis-
sions from combustion plants, oil refineries, coke
ovens, iron and steel plants, and factories making
cement, glass, lime, brick, ceramics, pulp and paper.
By now emissions trading has developed into one of
the EU’s major instruments to combat climate
change and both, the European Commission and
the European Council have stated that they regard
the EU ETS as an ‘‘essential instrument for achiev-
ing the medium- and long-term emission reductions
that are necessary to stabilise greenhouse gas con-centrations in the atmosphere.
Based on the fact that policy-making in the EU is
embedded into a multi-level governance system
which encourages the emergence of policy networks
it has been elucidated how the European emissions
trading scheme has been established in the frame-
work of an (informal) policy network built on the
sharing of knowledge about emissions trading. It
is argued that the European Emissions Trading
Directive has been developed by an issue-specific
policy network: the European policy network on
emissions trading which has been established by
staff members from DG Environment, including
experts from consultancies, environmental NGOs
and the business sector. It is concluded that thesharing of knowledge about emissions trading and
design options for emissions trading schemes was
the key momentum for the establishment and conti-
nuity of this policy network and that the possession
of knowledge and the control over the knowledge
being shared were the main factors to allow for a
few staff members from DG Environment to play
a dominant role as policy entrepreneurs for the
development of the emissions trading directive, even
beyond their formal role of just proposing the
scheme as representatives from the EU
Commission.
From a sociological perspective this ties up with
the debate on the relationship between knowledge
and power going back to Francis Bacon’s famous
aphorism ‘scientia potentia est’, these days usually
translated as ‘‘knowledge is power
”
, from his book
Meditationes Sacrae
(1597). The analysis above
clearly has shown that ‘‘knowledge and information
are a resource that identifies the powerful from the
non-powerful
”
(
Bennett & Howlett, 1992, p. 290
)
as the EU ETS has largely been established by a
few effective policy entrepreneurs from DG Envi-
ronment on the basis of the knowledge they gained
from – consciously or unconsciously – managing the
European policy network on emissions trading.
Most likely, they would not have been able to take
up this dominant role if they had not had the possi-
bility to always be a step ahead as regards knowl-
edge about emissions trading compared to other,
formally more powerful participants in the negotia-
tion process.
This puts the acquisition of knowledge at the cen-
tre of modern policy-making. Yet, in policy-making
processes knowledge is not
per se
linked with power.
Power depends on the kind of knowledge someone
disposes of as
Foucault (1991)
has already discussed
in his work on ‘governmentality’, a term which
points to the notion that power – in the sense of
governmental power – is not essentially limited to
the state and that power is increasingly dependent
on the availability of a specific kind of knowledge.
In this regard,
Crozier and Friedberg (1993, p.
50f)
. have identified expert knowledge as an impor-
tant source of power for an actor in a network.
Powerful is someone who has issue-specific knowl-
edge relevant for a certain policy, in this case knowl-
edge about emissions trading, in particular
knowledge about how it works and knowledge
about the potential (economic) impacts of different
design features of emissions trading schemes. Those
who had such knowledge – experts from consultancies, environmental NGOs, individual companies
and business associations – were able to influence
the policy-making process in the framework of the
European policy network on emissions trading
which they were a part of as knowledgeable individ-
uals. But in the end, the most knowledgeable indi-
viduals were also the most powerful ones: some
staff members from DG Environment that were able
to take up the role of policy entrepreneurs based on
their role as ‘managers of knowledge generation’
within the European policy network on emissions
trading.
However, it requires further research whether
these conclusions also apply to policy-making pro-
cesses regarding the development of other policy
instruments. Is it really the existence of an issue-spe-
cific policy network which enables some members of
the network to become policy entrepreneurs, and is
this based on being more knowledgeable than other
members of the network? And could it have been
that other
non-state
members of the policy network
instead of staff members from DG Environment
could have taken up the role as policy entrepreneurs
or is the condition to take up a dominant role rather
attached to the hierarchy criterion of being a repre-
sentative from the state and of being formally
responsible for steering the policy-making process?
These questions may be pulled together with the
theoretical discussion if governance processes in
multi-level systems can better be grasped by the con-
cept of hierarchy, market or network (
Mayntz,
1996; Powell, 1990; Weyer, 2000
). It seems as that
knowledge might serve as an important explanan-
dum in this debate.