دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 19807
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

نگاهی به داخل : تعرفه کربن در مقابل پیشرفت های داخلی در سیستم های انتشار تجاری

عنوان انگلیسی
A look inwards: Carbon tariffs versus internal improvements in emissions-trading systems
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
19807 2012 12 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Energy Economics, Volume 34, Supplement 2, December 2012, Pages S228–S239

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
سیاست آب و هوا - تعرفه های کربن - انتشار تجاری - تعادل عمومی قابل محاسبه
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Climate policy,Carbon tariffs,Emissions trading,Computable general equilibrium
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  نگاهی به داخل : تعرفه کربن در مقابل پیشرفت های داخلی در سیستم های انتشار تجاری

چکیده انگلیسی

Subglobal climate policies will be the norm for some years to come. However, several options exist for improving the efficiency of domestic emissions regulation. A prominent but contentious policy option for improving the external efficiency is the implementation of carbon tariffs on non-regulating regions. This is thought to reduce carbon leakage and increase domestic production, albeit at the cost of non-regulating countries. In contrast, internal efficiency improvements can be more collaborative in type. Among others, they include extending and linking of domestic emissions-trading systems. This study compares the relative economic impacts of those policy options if Annex I countries would follow one or the other. The study uses a computable-general-equilibrium model of the global world economy and develops a set of emissions-trading and carbon-tariff scenarios with various degrees of sectoral and regional coverage. For a globally effective Annex I emissions-reduction target of 20%, the results indicate that linking Annex I countries' domestic emissions-trading systems and expanding their sectoral coverage could yield greater global welfare improvements than implementing carbon tariffs on energy-intensive goods imported from non-Annex I countries. While non-Annex I countries would be significantly better off without facing carbon tariffs on their exports, Annex I countries could gain from either policy. The relative gains from linking and extending the sectoral coverage of domestic emissions-trading systems are greater for early policy implementation within a large Annex I coalition of climate-regulating countries, while late implementation within a small coalition would yield greater relative welfare gains from imposing carbon tariffs. The results suggest that, in addition to the political benefits, there exists an economic rationale for substituting the external efficiency improvements associated with implementing carbon tariffs with internal ones associated with extending Annex I countries' emissions-trading systems.

مقدمه انگلیسی

Current climate policies are fragmented and subglobal. Emissions abatement efforts are dichotomously divided between industrialized Annex I countries with legal emissions reduction commitments and developing non-Annex I countries without such commitments. The subglobal implementation of carbon pricing and the resulting price differentials between implementing and non-implementing countries have raised several concerns in the implementing countries. Some worry that domestic industries might suffer competitive disadvantages vis-à-vis international imports from non-abating countries. Others stress the risk of carbon leakage, i.e., increases in emissions in non-implementing countries through shifts in consumption demand and production, which could undermine the effectiveness of domestic emissions-reductions efforts (Dröge et al., 2009). In this context, some Annex I countries have proposed to implement carbon tariffs on imports from non-Annex I countries that have not agreed to adopt binding emissions-reduction commitments. Levying an import tariff in proportion to the carbon content of the imported good is thought to reduce carbon leakage and to preserve the competitiveness of domestic industries vis-à-vis international imports from non-abating countries (van Asselt and Biermann, 2007). From a theoretical perspective, implementing carbon tariffs is thought to increase the cost-efficiency of subglobal climate policies (Hoel, 1996 and Markusen, 1975). This is expected to benefit Annex I countries as carbon leakage is compensating through the comparatively cheaper emissions reductions in the exporting non-Annex I countries. However, while some numerical economic analyses indicate that implementing carbon tariffs could partially reduce carbon leakage and increase domestic consumption in the tariff-implementing regions (Böhringer et al., 2011, Burniaux et al., 2010 and Winchester et al., 2011), their distributional effects make them politically contentious. They are likely to place considerable burden with significant welfare losses on developing countries on whose exports the tariffs are imposed (Babiker and Rutherford, 2005, Dröge and Kemfert, 2005, Mattoo et al., 2009 and Springmann, 2012). This could have significant political and legal repercussions. For example, China denounced plans for carbon tariffs as trade protectionism for domestic industries, illegal under WTO law and threatened with trade war should carbon tariffs be adopted (Voituriez and Wang, 2011). More broadly, the political tensions arising from the adoption of carbon tariffs could further impede negotiations for a global climate agreement within the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC). Politically, carbon tariffs divide countries into potentially tariff-imposing Annex I countries with legal emissions-reduction commitments and potentially targeted non-Annex I countries without legal commitments. However, this distinction is not as clear-cut as it may seem. For example, several non-Annex I countries, such as China and South Korea are considering implementing emissions-trading schemes within this decade (Hood, 2010). On the other hand, many Annex I countries have not yet adopted comprehensive carbon-pricing policies and the emissions-trading schemes that exist, such as the European Union Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS) and the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI) in the USA are plagued by problems of overallocation of emissions permits (World Bank, 2011). Before extending domestic emissions regulation through the implementation of carbon tariffs, it might therefore be more appropriate for Annex I countries to further the improvement of domestic climate policies and the linking of existing and planned emissions-trading schemes. This would circumvent the political and legal problems associated with carbon tariffs and, in addition, be more in line with the UNFCCC principle of common but differentiated responsibility.1 While each of those two policy trajectories may have different political goals,2 either trajectory could be used from an economic perspective to increase the cost-efficiency of domestic abatement efforts in Annex I countries. Carbon tariffs induce external efficiency improvements by indirectly regulating those non-Annex I emissions that are associated with the production of export goods, whereas the expansion and linking of emissions-trading systems in Annex I countries induce internal efficiency improvements by enabling a more efficient sectoral and regional distribution of abatement efforts across Annex I countries. It should be noted that, in principle, internal and external efficiency improvements could be pursued together. For example, Grubb (2011) argues that the implementation of carbon tariffs on non-Annex I countries could provide an initiative for reducing the free distribution of emissions allowances to trade-exposed industries as is the current practice within some Annex I countries. In that case, external efficiency improvements would go hand in hand with internal ones. However, the fierce political debate surrounding carbon tariffs with references to potential trade wars suggests that this policy option bears great political risks which could obliterate any potential efficiency improvements and, in addition, have further repercussions on initiatives for improving the internal efficiency of abatement efforts. For example, the divergent opinions that exist across Annex I countries on the desirability of carbon tariffs would likely hamper the ETS-design harmonization that is needed for different emissions-trading systems to be linked. More generally, the policy options of implementing carbon tariffs and extending the coverage of Annex I countries' emissions-trading systems have different incentive structures which make them incompatible as long-term policy trajectories on the international level (across Annex I countries, as well as globally). Carbon tariffs are perceived as politically confrontational which is inconsistent with those cooperative initiatives that are aimed at linking different emissions-trading systems, in the long term, between Annex I and non-Annex I countries but, given the range of differing opinions on carbon tariffs, also within Annex I countries in the short term. On the other hand, initiatives aimed at linking emissions-trading systems across Annex I countries can be interpreted as a first step towards pursuing further linkages with those emissions-trading systems that are emerging in non-Annex I countries, something which would remove the basis for carbon tariffs being implemented.3 This study analyzes whether besides the political appeal, there exist also an economic rationale for pursuing internal efficiency improvements from linking emissions-trading systems in Annex I countries over the external efficiency improvements following from imposing carbon tariffs on non-Annex I countries. Theoretically, the linking and extending of emissions-trading schemes equalizes marginal-abatement costs between the regions and sectors covered. This leads to gains from trade in emissions allowances and associated increases in consumption and welfare in those regions and sectors (see, e.g., Tietenberg, 2006). While the outcome could, in principle, be different in second-best (real-world) settings (Babiker et al., 2004), several model studies have indicated the benefits from extending the coverage of emissions trading systems. For example, Weyant and Hill (1999) indicate significant benefits from emissions-trading across all Annex I countries for a cost-efficient fulfillment of their emissions-reduction obligations under the Kyoto Protocol, whereas Böhringer et al., 2005 and Böhringer et al., 2009 and Klepper and Peterson (2004) highlight the cost-saving potential of extending the sectoral coverage of the EU ETS. This study builds on those earlier assessments and analyses the potential gains from extending the sectoral and regional coverage of emissions-trading systems within Annex I regions vis-à-vis the implementation of carbon tariffs by Annex I countries on energy-intensive imports from non-Annex I countries. While each of those policies has been assessed before separately, no strict comparison of the policies' relative effects and their respective trade-offs has been made in a numerical setting. This study intends to fill this gap. For that purpose, it uses a computable general equilibrium model of the global world economy which tracks changes in trade flows, carbon-dioxide (CO2) emissions, as well as economic output and prices. The study develops a set of indicative emissions-trading and carbon-tariff scenarios, and it analyzes the trade-offs along each policy trajectory in terms of a cost-effectiveness analysis of attaining a specified (global) emissions level. Although the focus of this study is on the policies' economic impacts, in particular on welfare, it also assesses their effects on GDP, the production and exports of energy-intensive goods, and carbon leakage. The analysis is structured as follows. Section 2 describes the structure of the computable-general-equilibrium model, as well as the database and aggregation used in this study. Section 3 highlights the model scenarios and policy trajectories defined for the analysis. Section 4 presents the results of the main scenarios, while Section 5 includes a comprehensive sensitivity analysis that evaluated some of the key abstractions made in the study's main scenarios. Section 6 concludes.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

Subglobal climate policies will be the norm for some years to come. However, several options exist for improving the efficiency of domestic emissions regulation. A prominent but contentious policy option for improving the external efficiency is the implementation of carbon tariffs on non-regulating regions. This is thought to reduce carbon leakage and increase domestic production, albeit at the cost of non-regulating countries. In contrast, internal efficiency improvements are inward looking and can be more collaborative in type. Among others, they include extending and linking of domestic emissions-trading systems. This study compares the relative economic impacts of those policy options. This study's main results indicate that extending the sectoral and regional coverage of Annex I countries' emissions-trading systems could yield greater global welfare improvements than implementing carbon tariffs on energy-intensive goods imported from non-Annex I countries. While non-Annex I countries would be significantly better off without facing carbon tariffs on their exports, Annex I countries could gain from either policy.27 For the latter, extending the coverage of emissions-trading systems generates welfare improvements primarily by equalizing marginal-abatement costs and the associated gains from trade in emissions permit, whereas implementing carbon tariffs on energy-intensive imports generates welfare improvements through increases in domestic production and terms-of-trade effects in that sector. Under the main scenarios' parameter constellation, the welfare benefits for Annex I countries that result from extending the sectoral and regional coverage of their emissions-trading systems exceed those that result from implementing carbon tariffs on energy-intensive goods imported from non-Annex I countries. This result holds strictly for extending Annex I countries' regional emissions-trading systems to international ones covering all sectors. For extensions to international ones with partial sectoral coverage the welfare benefits are comparable but exceeded by those following from implementing carbon tariffs. The results are robust with respect to several changes in the key parameters governing the efficiency of extending emissions-trading systems and implementing carbon tariffs. In particular, the welfare ordering is preserved under changes in the overall emissions-reduction objective and the emissions-reduction allocation between sectors covered under the ETS and those which are not. While changes in some scenarios can occur, the results for a full ETS extension from regional emissions-trading systems with partial sectoral coverage to economy-wide international ETS are also robust with respect to changes in the elasticities governing trade substitution and fossil-fuel supply, as well as to changes in the tariff level associated with different methods to calculate the emissions embodied in non-Annex I countries' imports. However, the welfare ordering for Annex I countries could reverse for changes in the year of policy implementation and the coalition size of emissions-abating countries. An indicative forward calibration to 2020 suggests that the welfare benefits for Annex I countries that result from implementing carbon tariffs could exceed those that result from extending the sectoral or regional coverage of their emissions-trading systems when implemented in 2020. The prime reason for this reversal is the projected increase in marginal-abatement costs in the future which, on the one side, reduces the efficiency improvements that can be achieved by extending emissions-trading systems, and on the other side, increases the potential revenue stream from implementing carbon tariffs on non-regulating countries. Reducing the coalition size from all Annex I countries to the current nucleus of emissions-regulating countries results in a reversal of the original welfare ordering for similar reasons. Thus, early implementation and enlarging the coalition of emissions-regulating countries would increase the relative benefits of internal efficiency improvements through extensions of emissions-trading systems, while late implementation and a small coalition of climate-regulating countries would increase the relative benefits of external efficiency improvements through implementing carbon tariffs on imports from non-regulating countries. Albeit tacitly, current negotiations within the UNFCCC clearly move towards the conditions for increasing the relative benefits of collaborative action and internal efficiency improvements. The Durban Platform established in 2011 at the 17th Conference of the Parties is tasked to develop a universal legal agreement on climate change and emissions-reduction commitments by 2015 which should be implemented by 2020. Such an agreement, together with the climate policies already emerging in developing countries, would make the policy of imposing carbon tariffs on exports from non-regulating countries obsolete. A more politically sustainable policy option compared to implementing carbon tariffs could therefore be to support the UNFCCC process by concentrating on internal efficiency improvements, such as those from extending and linking of domestic emissions-trading systems. The EU Commission's (2009) policy vision of a linked OECD carbon market within this decade clearly points in that direction. The results obtained in this study suggest that in addition to the political appeal, there exist also an economic rationale for pursuing internal efficiency improvements from extending and linking of emissions-trading systems over external ones from implementing carbon tariffs. Notwithstanding, this study's analysis is far from complete and subject to several caveats. In particular, the computable-general-equilibrium model and the model scenarios devised for this study are highly indicative and abstract from many legal, political, and regulatory issues. For example, considerable efforts would be necessary to overcome current barriers to pursuing the extending and linking of emissions-trading systems. In particular, critical design elements, such as sectoral coverage and the inclusion of cost-containing measures would need to be harmonized (see, e.g., Tuerk et al., 2009). Although this study's sensitivity analysis indicates a certain robustness of general impact directions, additional and more detailed assessments that would include such political and regulatory externalities would be beneficial.