دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 26098
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

مدیریت شناور به عنوان یک استراتژی برای رسیدن به انتخاب اهداف سیاست های پولی

عنوان انگلیسی
Managed floating as a strategy to achieve selected monetary policy objectives
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
26098 2006 18 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Journal of Economics and Business, Volume 58, Issues 5–6, October–November 2006, Pages 447–464

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
اهداف سیاست های پولی -      رژیم نرخ ارز -      تورم -
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Monetary policy objectives, Exchange rate regimes, Inflation,
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  مدیریت شناور به عنوان یک استراتژی برای رسیدن به انتخاب اهداف سیاست های پولی

چکیده انگلیسی

The paper considers the connection between exchange rate regimes and economic performance as measured by inflation, output growth, and their volatility. It is argued first that the choice of an intermediate exchange rate regime is complicated by potential conflicts with the requirements of central bank transparency and accountability. These are considered to be longer run questions. Next, three types of managed floating regimes are defined. A variety of counterfactual experiments are shown to illustrate that a managed float, such that the objective of monetary policy is expressed in terms of an inflation target, will produce the most desirable macroeconomic outcome. The counterfactuals are supplemented with estimates of forward-looking Taylor rules to ascertain whether such rules are informative under a managed floating scenario. In general, the answer is that central bank reaction functions become less useful when the exchange rate regime is an intermediate one.

مقدمه انگلیسی

Skepticism about the usefulness of de jure exchange rate classification schemes of the kind reported by the International Monetary Fund (i.e., as in its once regular publication Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions) has spawned a burgeoning literature that proposes de facto exchange rate regime classifications (e.g., see Fischer, 2001; Levy-Yeyayti & Sturzenegger, 2001). For example, Fischer (2001) concludes that there is an apparent tendency toward “corner” solutions in exchange rate regime choices with a distinct preference in recent years for floating over the fixed variety of exchange rate regime (also see Bubula & Ötker, 2002). The bi-polar view is not, however, without its critics. Some have pointed to a “fear” of floating wherein countries that notionally prefer to float nevertheless intervene regularly to prevent full flexibility of the exchange rate (e.g., Calvo & Reinhart, 2002). Others have pointed out that some countries display an aversion to truly fixing their exchange rate, preferring instead to allow for the contingency that the existing peg may be altered if it becomes too costly to defend or macroeconomic conditions require a realignment of some kind ( Willett, 2003). Therefore, there is skepticism that the two corners solution is the preferred explanation for the apparent evolution of exchange rate regimes over the past 2 or 3 decades (also see Angkinand, Chiu, & Willett, 2005). Instead, intermediate regimes of the managed floating variety seem to be fairly prevalent around the globe. More recently, some of these intermediate regimes have been designed as vehicles to constrain countries to follow monetary policies that would deliver low and stable inflation rates. Yet, such exchange rate regimes are not well understood nor are they widely studied. A common theme in this literature is the assumption that managed floating is principally about attempts to manipulate exchange rate levels. Yet, many countries that the IMF used to classify as operating under an “independently floating” regime have in fact from time to time intervened not to achieve a particular target level for the exchange rate but to manipulate the size of exchange rate changes, or the uncertainty around exchange rate movements. One problem is that a standard definition of what is meant by the term “managed floating” appears to be missing. Does any form of central bank intervention in foreign exchange markets constitute a form of managed floating? Does managed floating refer only to setting a target level for the exchange rate, perhaps within some band to limit exchange rate volatility? What about the uncertainty surrounding exchange rate movements? More generally, does it matter whether the central bank or the government is responsible for exchange rate policy? The latter consideration raises questions about where accountability lies for decisions about whether and, under what conditions, foreign exchange intervention takes place, as well as the maintenance of the durability of the exchange rate regime itself. Moreover, managed floating of any kind raise issues about the degree to which the central bank, in particular, can be transparent about foreign exchange operations. Thus, for example, whereas countries that are ostensibly floaters have, sooner or later, made public intervention and other data about their foreign exchange operations (e.g., US, Germany, Japan), others (e.g., Asian economies) have been rather opaque about their exchange rate objectives. While all the foregoing questions cannot be dealt with in one paper, the bottom line is that countries first have to decide for themselves how much they value monetary and fiscal independence. Here too, matters are more complicated for even if policy autonomy is considered highly desirable, choosing a floating regime may not be suitable if, for example, a country has not historically demonstrated a capacity to implement sound economic policies. The paper examines the macroeconomic implications of choosing exchange rate regimes of the managed floating variety in both the long and short-run. First, it is argued that a successful exchange rate regime must be dependent on institutional considerations, in particular the twin characteristics of central bank accountability and transparency. Nevertheless, the impact of institutional factors may only be felt in the long-run. In the short-run, policy makers are more concerned about the effects of a particular exchange rate regime on inflation and output growth. While comparative studies of economic performance for a group of countries that have adopted different exchange rate regimes are useful, there are sufficient doubts surrounding exchange rate classification schemes to recommend a different approach to studying some of the relevant issues. Three versions of a managed floating regime are defined and, relying in counterfactual experiments, we explore what these would have implied for economic and monetary policy performance for Australia, Canada and New Zealand. These are three countries acknowledged by most to have followed as closely as possible the basic tenets of a floating exchange rate regime.1 The same countries are also considered to be the archetypical small open economies and, hence, can serve as a point of reference for many emerging market economies. In addition, all three countries have one major trading partner, the US for Canada and Australia, Australia for New Zealand. The economic influence of the principal trading partner looms large in the domestic economic affairs of each of the three countries examined here.2 The paper asks what the mean and variance of inflation and output growth would have been had one of the three versions of a managed floating regime considered in this paper been adopted by countries that actually had floating exchange rates. The same counterfactual experiments are then used to generate the path for a monetary rule under a managed float, and what this would have implied about the tightness and ease of monetary policy over time. It is suggested that special consideration ought to be given to central bank accountability and transparency under a managed floating regime. Consequently, in choosing the exchange rate regime, a managed float of some kind can serve only as a halfway house on the road toward some type of corner solution.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

This paper has considered the problem of implementing a monetary policy strategy when an intermediate exchange rate regime is adopted. It is first argued that choosing any type of managed floating regime has potential consequences for the twin requirements of central bank accountability and transparency that have become much discussed in current policy circles. Indeed, it appears that floating regimes are most compatible with a high level of both central bank accountability and transparency. A difficulty with managed floats is that the trade-off between interest rate and exchange rate changes are difficult to communicate to the public. Next, the paper illustrates the consequences of regime choice by defining three types of managed floats. One version imposes an exchange rate target, another an interest rate target, while a third approach defines the intermediate regime in the context of an inflation target. A structural VAR is then specified and estimated and counterfactual experiments are then conducted. An inflation targeting regime always produces the most desirable combinations of inflation and output growth while an exchange rate objective is found to have the most deleterious impact on output growth. Finally, the paper considers the implementation of monetary policy as interpreted through a Taylor rule. First, I estimate forward looking policy rules for a selection of countries that adopted freely floating exchange rates, a managed float, or pegged their exchange rate. Next, I ask what would the policy rule look like if the country in question had adopted a managed float. The resulting counterfactuals suggest that Taylor rules are relatively less informative about how a central bank reacts to inflation and output gaps under managed floating than in a freely floating regime. Future research might consider, for example, how different assumptions about credibility affect output and inflation across exchange regime types. One might also conduct a reverse-type experiment than in this paper, namely take countries that followed an intermediate type exchange rate regime and ask what output growth and inflation would have look like if these same countries had a pure floating exchange rate.