جهانی شدن سیاست پولی و مالی
کد مقاله | سال انتشار | تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی |
---|---|---|
26478 | 2008 | 13 صفحه PDF |
Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)
Journal : Journal of Monetary Economics, Volume 55, Issue 8, November 2008, Pages 1363–1375
چکیده انگلیسی
Recent data show substantial increases in the size of gross external asset and liability positions. The implications of these developments for optimal conduct of monetary policy are analyzed in a standard open economy model which is augmented to allow for endogenous portfolio choice. The model shows that monetary policy takes on new importance due to its impact on nominal asset returns. Nevertheless, the case for price stability as an optimal monetary rule remains. In fact, it is reinforced. Even without nominal price rigidities, price stability is optimal because it enhances the risk sharing properties of nominal bonds.
مقدمه انگلیسی
The growth in the size and complexity of international financial markets has been one of the most striking aspects of the world economy over the last decade. Lane and Milesi-Ferretti, 2001 and Lane and Milesi-Ferretti, 2006 document the increase in gross cross-border holdings of bond and equities, describing this as a process of financial globalization. Economists and policy makers have speculated on the implications of financial globalization for the design of monetary policy. 1 Most central banks now follow a policy of inflation targeting. Under this policy, price stability, appropriately defined, is the principal goal of monetary policy. Is this conclusion altered by the presence of large cross border gross holdings of financial assets, where movements in asset prices and exchange rates may have significant wealth redistribution effects? This paper explores the implications of financial globalization for the design of monetary policy. We can address the question raised above, because our model determines the structure of gross holdings of cross-country financial assets. The principal finding is that endogenous portfolio structure does not alter the case for price stability as an optimal monetary policy. In fact, it may even reinforce this case. In an environment where financial markets are incomplete, price stability is desirable because it enhances the international risk-sharing properties of nominal assets, even without nominal goods price rigidities. A theoretical foundation for price stability has been given by King and Wolman (1999), Woodford (2003), and others, using sticky-price dynamic general equilibrium models. A monetary rule devoted to stabilizing prices eliminates the inefficiency of costly price adjustment. In an open economy, however, the optimality of price stability as the sole goal of monetary policy depends on the structure of international financial markets. Benigno and Benigno (2003) show that stability of producer prices is optimal when financial markets are complete. But Benigno (2001) and Obstfeld and Rogoff (2002) show that the absence of full international risk-sharing may interact with the inefficiency arising from sticky prices, so that price stability may not constitute the unique optimal goal of monetary policy. A drawback of many of these papers is that international financial markets are modeled either by the absence of any type of international risk-sharing (e.g. trade in non-contingent bonds) or by full risk-sharing (complete markets). In reality, international financial markets seem to be somewhere in the middle. Once allowance is made for endogenous portfolio choice, it is possible that monetary policy rules actually affect the structure or efficiency of international financial markets. Thus, the analysis of monetary policy with endogenous portfolio structure is an important direction for this literature. Research along these lines has been hindered by the difficulty of integrating portfolio choice into dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models. This paper resolves this difficulty by using a methodology developed in Devereux and Sutherland (2006), which can incorporate optimal portfolio choice in a standard DSGE setting in a tractable way. This is combined with an otherwise standard two-country model of an open economy with staggered price-setting. The paper allows for a range of financial structures, differing in the number of assets traded across countries. In one case, the only asset is a non-contingent real bond, and there is no portfolio choice at all. In another case, there is trade in nominal bonds and equities and given our stochastic environment, markets are complete. In an intermediate case, nominal bonds denominated in each country's currency can be traded. Portfolio choice is then endogenous, but asset markets are incomplete. The model delivers analytical solutions for gross asset holdings under each financial market configuration. We ask how monetary policy interacts with portfolio choice in affecting macro-economic outcomes, investigate how monetary policy influences the degree of international risk-sharing, and characterize an optimal monetary policy. With trade in both bonds and equities full international risk-sharing is achieved, for any monetary policy. In this case the portfolio composition of bonds and equities is independent of monetary policy. Then price stability is an optimal policy for conventional reasons, since it eliminates the welfare losses coming from slow price adjustment.2 On the other hand, when asset trade is restricted to a real non-contingent bond, deviating from price stability is in general desirable in order to alleviate risk-sharing inefficiencies. But in the intermediate case, with trade in nominal bonds, monetary policy affects the composition of portfolios. Monetary policy plays a dual role. First, it can be used so as to support the flexible price equilibrium of the economy. But monetary policy can also enhance the degree of international risk-sharing itself, by improving the hedging properties of nominal bonds. This second property of policy is conceptually independent of the first; it remains useful even in a flexible price economy. We find that in an environment where nominal bonds are traded, a policy of strict price stability will endogenously generate full international risk-sharing. Strict price stability is desirable on two counts. It supports the flexible price outcome, and it also allows nominal bond returns to offer full risk-sharing against country specific productivity shocks. Even if prices are fully flexible, there is still a non-trivial welfare case for price stability, if asset markets are incomplete. The model implies that countries are holding large offsetting gross nominal asset positions, so that exchange rate movements can generate substantial ‘valuation effects’. But the presence of these effects does not directly change the optimal monetary rule. Because portfolios are chosen optimally, the wealth redistribution arising from exchange-rate-induced valuation effects represent the workings of an efficient international financial structure. Moreover, monetary authorities do not have to be concerned with these redistributions. It is desirable to use the exchange rate in the traditional Friedman (1953) manner—to generate efficient terms-of-trade adjustment. The new insight from this paper is that Friedman's prescription may hold even without his underlying assumption of sluggish nominal goods price adjustment. When risk sharing is obtained via trade in nominal bonds, the Friedman argument—that it is better to use the exchange rate to facilitate terms of trade adjustment rather than price levels—is supported, even in a fully flexible price economy. This paper is related to a growing literature on the analysis of portfolio composition and financial markets in dynamic general equilibrium models. The method used here is developed in Devereux and Sutherland, 2006 and Devereux and Sutherland, 2007c. Related papers are Engel and Matsumoto (2006), Evans and Hnatkovska (2005) and Kollmann (2006). Engel and Matsumoto (2006) incorporate endogenous portfolio choice into a complete markets version of a sticky-price open economy macro model, focusing on the ‘home equity bias’ puzzle. They do not directly analyze the role of monetary policy. Kollmann (2006) and Evans and Hnatkovska (2005) construct non-monetary dynamic general equilibrium environments with endogenous portfolio choice. Kollmann's (2006) analysis is based on complete markets, also examining the determinants of home equity bias. Evans and Hnatkovska (2005) employ a numerical approximation method to solve for portfolio choice.3 A slightly older literature has examined the determinants of trade in nominal bonds. Svensson (1989) develops a two period cash in advance model to analyze the determinants of nominal bond trading and the welfare gains to asset trade, but does not characterize the specific gross portfolio positions or the determination of optimal monetary policy. Bacchetta and van Wincoop (2000) also develop a two period endowment economy model, and focus on the impact of nominal bonds on capital flows. An early fundamental contribution is Helpman and Razin (1978). The next section develops the open economy model. Section 3 discusses the approach to solving for optimal portfolios. Section 4 solves for the optimal portfolios and discusses the effects of monetary policy on portfolios. Some conclusions follow.
نتیجه گیری انگلیسی
This paper shows how a simple benchmark two-country sticky-price open-economy macro model can be amended so as to incorporate endogenous portfolio choice. We solve for the optimal portfolio holdings of national equities and nominal bonds, and show how these depend on the magnitude of stochastic shocks, the degree of price stickiness, and the stance of monetary policy. A key result is that a monetary policy of strict price stability is desirable, not just because it sustains the flexible price equilibrium outcome of the real economy, but also because it endogenously generates full international risk-sharing. This argument for price stability holds even in a fully flexible price economy, and arises due to the fact that such a policy maximizes the risk-hedging properties of nominal bond returns. More generally, our results suggest that while financial globalization alters the environment within which monetary policy operates, it may not alter the fundamental objectives of optimal monetary policy.