درسهایی از بانک مرکزی انگلستان در 'کاهش کمی و سایر سیاست های پولی "غیر متعارف"
کد مقاله | سال انتشار | تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی |
---|---|---|
27742 | 2012 | 12 صفحه PDF |
Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)
Journal : International Review of Financial Analysis, Volume 25, December 2012, Pages 94–105
چکیده انگلیسی
This paper investigates the effectiveness of the ‘quantitative easing’ policy, as officially implemented by the Bank of England since March 2009. A policy of the same name had previously been implemented in Japan, which serves as a reference. While the majority of the previous literature has measured the effectiveness of QE by its impact on interest rates, in this paper the effectiveness of all Bank of England policies, including QE, is measured by their impact on the declared goal of the QE policy, namely nominal GDP growth. Further, unlike other works on policy evaluation, in this paper we use the general-to-specific econometric modelling methodology (a.k.a. the ‘Hendry’ or ‘LSE’ methodology) in order to determine the relative importance of Bank of England policies, including QE. The empirical analysis indicates that QE as defined and announced in March 2009 had no apparent effect on the UK economy. Meanwhile, it is found that a policy of ‘quantitative easing’ as defined in the original sense of the term (Werner, 1995c) is supported by empirical evidence: a stable relationship between a lending aggregate (disaggregated M4 lending, singling out bank credit for GDP transactions) and nominal GDP is found. The findings imply that the central bank should more directly target the growth of bank credit for GDP-transactions, which was still contracting in late 2011. A number of measures exist to boost it, but they have hitherto not been taken
مقدمه انگلیسی
Quantitative monetary targets were the mainstay of monetary policy in the early 1980s. Later that decade, however, most central banks abandoned this approach, since it was considered to have failed. As Werner (2012) argues, this failure was largely due to the perceived instability of velocity and the money demand function in many countries since the 1980s. Since then central banks have emphasised interest rate policies in their official statements, and central bank watching has come to focus on interest rate decisions and how actions of central banks might affect interest rates, in line with the ‘new monetary policy consensus’, as proposed, among others, by Woodford (2003). The interest rate-centred approach to monetary policy implementation became predominant despite a conspicuous absence of empirical evidence that interest rates are negatively correlated with economic growth in a consistent and robust manner, and that statistical causation runs from interest rates to the economy. Over the prior three decades it had gradually become an increasingly open secret that in empirical studies interest rates often did not ‘behave well’.1 The interest rate-based monetary consensus encountered a further major empirical challenge when more than a dozen interest rate reductions over a decade failed to stimulate the Japanese economy in the 1990s. The Bank of Japan had previously been one of the major supporters of the interest-based approach, arguing that due to their preference for interest rate smoothing they could not also control the money supply. This approach was unceremoniously abandoned on 19 March 2001, as the Bank of Japan reverted to a regime of targeting quantitative monetary aggregates, namely bank reserves, while using open market operations to achieve it. Despite signifying a return to standard monetary targeting of the type that had been abandoned in the 1980s (in fact the oldest form, namely ‘narrow money’ targeting), the policy was, from 2002 onwards, presented as ‘new’, primarily by choosing a relatively new expression to describe it — ‘quantitative easing’ (QE) (see Voutsinas & Werner, 2010). In March 2009, the Bank of England followed suit and announced the introduction of ‘quantitative easing’, in circumstances that resembled the Japanese ones in a number of ways. The Federal Reserve also adopted a variety of new measures, many of which also centred on monetary operations defined by the quantity of injected funds, rather than their price — although avoiding the expression ‘quantitative easing’ in official statements.2 While the interest rate consensus view of monetary policy seemed to survive the Japanese challenge – Japan sometimes being dismissed as an outlier – the North Atlantic banking crisis and monetary policy responses by the Federal Reserve and Bank of England exposed its flaws. This dramatic shift in monetary policy regimes from prices to quantities calls for a thorough evaluation of the effectiveness of recent measures. Surprisingly, studies of their effectiveness have however focused on analysing their impact on interest rates.3 This seems counterintuitive, since they had been adopted precisely because the interest rate based approach had been abandoned by central banks, and despite the fact that researchers failed to provide any evidence that interest rates are in a stable relationship with a final target variable such as nominal GDP. If nothing else, this underlines the extent of the prior dominance of the interest rate based approach. It would seem that the prior preoccupation with interest rates has left an indelible mark in the minds of economists, many of whom take it for granted that it is sufficient to evaluate whether a policy tool affects interest rates. This focus on analysing the effect of QE (or similar policies) by their impact on interest rates has left researchers and policy-makers with little information about the effectiveness of such policy in influencing the macroeconomic variables that matter most to governments, central banks and the public at large. Voutsinas and Werner (2010) suggested therefore to examine the effectiveness of monetary policy in a nested general model of an ultimate goal that most stakeholders could agree with: nominal GDP growth. They employ this for an analysis of the accountability of the Japanese central bank, utilising the general-to-specific econometric modelling methodology (a.k.a. the ‘Hendry’ or ‘LSE’ method, following Hendry & Mizon, 1978). The final policy target of nominal GDP growth is regressed on a large number of explanatory variables, potential and actual tools and intermediate targets that were actually or could have been deployed by the central bank. With this approach, the effectiveness of actual and potential tools or intermediate targets can be empirically evaluated, including the significance of new policy regimes. They find no evidence that the reserve expansion policy had been effective. Another innovation is their use of disaggregated credit as one of the explanatory variables, on the basis that credit for GDP transactions is more likely to be in a stable relationship with nominal GDP, while credit for non-GDP transactions is associated with asset price movements (Werner, 1992, Werner, 1997a and Werner, 2005). This approach solves the problem of the ‘velocity decline’ that had confounded earlier attempts at identifying stable empirical models of nominal GDP. In the present paper the Voutsinas–Werner methodology is employed for the first time to assess the effectiveness of the policy announced by the Bank of England in March 2009, which is also referred to as ‘quantitative easing’ (QE). The choice of nominal GDP growth as policy goal is particularly uncontroversial in the UK case, because the Bank of England has stated explicitly that the ultimate target of its policy is indeed nominal GDP growth. The Bank of England staff (Joyce, Lasaosa, Stevens, & Tong, 2010) stated that the policy of QE was adopted “with the aim of … increasing nominal spending growth” (p. 1), while “…the effectiveness of the MPC's asset purchases [QE] will ultimately be judged by their impact on the wider macroeconomy” (p. 5). So far few empirical studies have been conducted on the UK case, and none adopting this methodology. According to Joyce et al. (2010) “Our analysis suggests that the [asset] purchases [of the central bank] have had a significant impact on financial markets and particularly gilt yields, but there is clearly more to learn about the transmission of those effects to the wider economy” (p. 4). It is the goal of this paper to investigate the transmission of monetary policy and the effect of particular tools and intermediate targets (actual and potential) “on the wider economy”, as measured by nominal GDP. We find that there is no empirical evidence that bank reserves, bond purchases, or even the maturity structure of central bank bond holdings – the key characteristics of the Bank of England's QE – have the predicted impact on nominal GDP. No evidence is found that the relationship between nominal GDP and its determinants changed in any way in March 2009. As a result, we conclude that we cannot demonstrate empirically that the new policy announced in March 2009 made any impact. Furthermore, the results suggest that the Bank of England would be well advised to give up targeting reserves and using bond purchases as its main policy tool, and instead adopt a policy of ‘quantitative easing’ defined in the original sense of the term as proposed in Japan in 1994 by one of the co-authors (Werner, 1995c, see below): Such a policy aims at expanding credit creation used for GDP transactions, and indeed a stable empirical relationship between a lending aggregate (disaggregated M4 lending for GDP transactions) and nominal GDP is found. The findings imply that BoE policy should more directly target the growth of bank credit for GDP-transactions, as suggested in Werner, 1992, Werner, 1994a, Werner, 1994b, Werner, 1994c, Werner, 1995a, Werner, 1995c, Werner, 1997b, Werner, 1997c and Werner, 2005 for post banking-crisis situations. In fact, despite the BoE's efforts, bank credit growth contracted by record amounts in late 2011, as a result of which the UK economy turned into a double-dip recession in the first half of 2012 — as was predicted by our model. The paper is organised as follows: In Section 2, the historical origin of the term ‘quantitative easing’ is briefly discussed, followed by an overview of the Bank of England's monetary policy and use of this term. Section 4 reviews the literature on the effectiveness of QE. Section 5 implements a new test of the effectiveness of QE in the UK. Section 6 concludes.
نتیجه گیری انگلیسی
The quantity equation relationship between M4 lending growth, when adjusted for non-GDP transactions (see Appendix 1), is found to be in a stable long-term relationship with nominal GDP growth. The lack of such disaggregation had previously been identified as the reason for the apparent ‘velocity decline’ (Werner, 1997a and Werner, 2005). Meanwhile, other monetary policy tools or intermediate targets do not perform in line with theory, calling for a revision of the equilibrium-based approaches. The ‘new consensus’ of monetary policy implementation by central banks had focussed on nominal short-term interest rates (see e.g. Curdia and Woodford, 2010, Lenza et al., 2010 and Woodford, 2003), at least until the 2008 crisis. However, contrary to the claims of this approach, interest rates are found to be positively correlated with GDP. This shows that earlier studies that defined the effectiveness of QE by its impact on interest rates may be misleading, since interest rates are positively, not negatively correlated with nominal GDP. The BoE's announcement of March 2009 claimed that a break with past policy was made and a new policy of significant asset purchases was adopted. However, central banks routinely engage in asset purchases and asset sales, without much-touted policy statements attached to them. In this paper, monetary policy is examined by analysing the relationship between a number of actual and potential monetary policy tools and intermediate targets on the one hand, and the target variable of nominal GDP growth on the other. Empirically it was found that there is no evidence that monetary policy changed in a meaningful way in March 2009, as claimed. Total assets do not appear to have a significant positive correlation with nominal GDP growth, while interest rates did not have a negative correlation – just as other literature had found, which is in contradiction to key aspects of prevailing theory. Total central bank asset growth was not found to be helpful as far as the recovery of the economy is concerned. It is thus unlikely to be attractive as a main monetary policy instrument. The ‘qualitative easing’ strategy of changing a central bank's balance sheet composition (by increasing long-term holdings of assets) does not seem to have a significant impact on the economy, as this particular indicator dropped out from the model. The findings raise the prospect of a revival of a more traditional, quantity-based approach, but modified by the use of disaggregated credit counterparts instead of monetary aggregates (Werner’s Quantity Theory of Credit).10 We conclude that BoE policy should more directly target the growth of bank credit for GDP-transactions, as suggested in Werner, 1992, Werner, 1994c, Werner, 1994a and Werner, 1997b for post banking-crisis situations. Despite the BoE's policies, bank credit growth contracted by record amounts in late 2011. Consequently, the UK economy turned into a double-dip recession in the first half of 2012 – as our model predicted. There seems no need to take recourse to ‘unorthodox’ monetary policy: targeting a broad monetary aggregate is an orthodox idea, albeit refined here by the use of a disaggregated credit counterpart. This appears to be a promising avenue for research and policy applications. As credit for GDP-transactions is found to have highest significance in explaining economic growth, policy-makers need to consider the methods that may influence this variable. Suggestions are made in Werner, 1994c, Werner, 1998a, Werner, 1998b and Werner, 2005 and include the substitution of bond issuance with government borrowing from banks. This would boost credit creation which, ironically, was the original meaning of the term ‘quantitative easing’. Another, more controversial method would be the re-introduction of a regime of credit guidance (‘window guidance’) to boost bank credit creation to finance corporate investment. Such proposals are also relevant for the eurozone, where the effectiveness of ECB policies is currently debated (see the first article of this special issue).