آزمایش تجربی رفتار گله ای در آزمایشگاه تنظیمات بازار سهام مصنوعی؛ مبانی رفتاری از حقایق تجربی بازده مالی
کد مقاله | سال انتشار | تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی |
---|---|---|
16162 | 2013 | 22 صفحه PDF |
Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)
Journal : Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, Volume 392, Issue 19, 1 October 2013, Pages 4351–4372
چکیده انگلیسی
Many scholars express concerns that herding behaviour causes excess volatility, destabilises financial markets, and increases the likelihood of systemic risk. We use a special form of the Strongly Typed Genetic Programming (STGP) technique to evolve a stock market divided into two groups—a small subset of artificial agents called ‘Best Agents’ and a main cohort of agents named ‘All Agents’. The ‘Best Agents’ perform best in term of the trailing return of a wealth moving average. We then investigate whether herding behaviour can arise when agents trade Dow Jones, General Electric, and IBM financial instruments in four different artificial stock markets. This paper uses real historical quotes of the three financial instruments to analyse the behavioural foundations of stylised facts such as leptokurtosis, non-IIDness, and volatility clustering. We found evidence of more herding in a group of stocks than in individual stocks, but the magnitude of herding does not contribute to the mispricing of assets in the long run. Our findings suggest that the price formation process caused by the collective behaviour of the entire market exhibit less herding and is more efficient than the segmented market populated by a small subset of agents. Hence, greater genetic diversity leads to greater consistency with fundamental values and market efficiency.
مقدمه انگلیسی
The majority of investors actively trade stocks instead of buying and holding a market portfolio. Active trading may move asset prices around the intrinsic value of the stock and increase long-run price volatility. Analysing herd behaviour in financial markets is of particular interest, because it might offer an explanation of excess volatility and bubbles. Traders experience herd behaviour when the knowledge that others are investing changes their decision from not investing to making the investment. In other words, investors copy the behaviour of other investors, leading to changes in their decision-making process after observing others. Investors ignore to a certain degree their private opinions and follow the market, leading to a switch from non-trading to trading. Herding might cause changes in the magnitude of trading activity, the assets traders invest in, or even their valuation. Herding behaviour explains why profit-maximising individuals with similar information react similarly in terms of investing funds [1]. The financial crises of the 1980s and 1990 have highlighted herding as a possible reason for excess volatility and financial system fragility. The authors of [2], [3] and [4] were among the first scholars to write about herd behaviour. They analyse herd behaviour under abstract conditions (in the context of fads, fashions, and customs) where privately informed individuals develop their decision-making process in sequence. These early research papers attempt to describe herding when a finite number of individuals have already chosen their actions and all following individuals abandon their own specific private information and herd. Devenow and Welch [5] suggest that agents disregard their prior beliefs and follow the actions of other agents, creating herding. Christie and Huang [6] assumed that herding is most pronounced when market returns are extreme. Their findings show that, when market agents abandon their own stock price forecasts in favour of the aggregate market behaviour, asset returns are very similar to the overall market return. A few years later, Avery and Zemsky [7] investigated herd behaviour in real financial market settings with stock prices determined by a market maker according to the order flow. The authors conclude that the price mechanism prevents the development of informational cascades (a market condition in which traders disregard their own information and imitate previous traders’ decisions, leading to herd behaviour). They show that informational cascades are impossible because new information can reach the market at any time; thus, consistent with steady informational flow, prices do not deviate significantly from fundamental values. Moreover, according to their findings, herd behaviour does not cause excess volatility and the mispricing of assets in the long run. Lakonishok, Shleifer, and Vishny [8] and Bikhchandani and Sharma [1] claim that there seems to be weaker evidence of herding behaviour in individual stocks than in groups of stocks. They stress that this does not exclude the possibility of more intensive herding in certain stocks such as stocks of a particular size or with particular performance records. The Marginal Trader Hypothesis (MTH), proposed by Forsythe et al. [9], states that a small fraction of savvy individuals are capable of setting market prices and strive for market efficiency. Marginal traders are described as well-informed and active traders who are more capable of inferring true price and willing to explore those inferences. The authors argue that, when one removes those ‘perfect’ individuals from the pool of traders, prediction markets lose their accuracy. Prediction markets are markets established to generate knowledge and forecasts about the likelihood of future events. Forsythe et al. [9] analyse data from the Iowa Presidential Stock Market (IPSM), which was successfully created in 1988 and operated as a computerised double-action market in order to forecast the vote shares of the presidential candidates in elections held in the same year. They combined market design and incentive structures familiar from laboratory experiments to find out how the 1988 US presidentials would finish. The accuracy of prediction they achieved was very impressive. However, it is difficult to test those theoretical assumptions directly. The literature related to herding behaviour in financial markets focuses primarily on statistical measures of clustering. The main difficulty from the empirical point of view comes from the fact that there is no database on the private information available to investors, and hence it is not possible to prove whether market agents strictly disregard their own information and imitate. This serious obstacle can be avoided in experimental settings such as an agent-based artificial stock market where the information possessed by traders can be controlled. Under laboratory settings, researchers can observe the private information available to individuals for decision-making purposes, and therefore it is possible to test the presence of herding. In a market simulation model that we created using Altreva Adaptive Modeler, artificial traders receive information about the value of a real security and observe the history of past trades. Based on this information, they decide if they want to buy or sell one or more units of the security. By observing how artificial agents deal with the same piece of public information and react to the decisions of the previous agents, we can detect the possible presence of herding behaviour. The modelling software that we use provides a rich environment to examine herd behaviour as artificial traders make independent decisions creating a heterogeneous market structure (the market is populated by 10,000 boundedly rational artificial agents, each with different trading rules and behaviour). Traders’ adaptive behaviour in our artificial stock market is modelled with an evolutionary computing technique called Strongly Typed Genetic Programming (STGP). The STGP evolves the trading rules at the micro level and co-evolves all agents through trading on the artificial market at the macro level. In this paper, we evaluate the price series of a group of stocks modelled by the Dow Jones and individual stocks represented by General Electric and IBM generated using two main groups of artificial agents—‘Best Agents’ and ‘All Agents’. We then use econometric evaluation to analyse the following topics. (i) Do price series generated by artificial stock market agents exhibit herding behaviour in individual stocks as well as in a group of stocks? (ii) Volatility analysis of price series generated by ‘Best Agents’ and ‘All Agents’. Is the Virtual Market price based on the behaviour of all agents less volatile in comparison with a small subset of agents? (iii) Artificial stock markets and the Efficient Market Hypothesis. Is the price series generated by ‘Best Agents’ more likely to conform to the Efficient Market Hypothesis, and therefore be more efficient? Chen and Yeh [10] developed a genetic programming (GP) based artificial stock market in order to investigate herding behaviour. Chen and Yeh’s paper was a good starting point, and we suggest several extensions to their approach based on the following important factors. – A greater number of artificial agents. While Chen and Yeh’s model consists of only 500 traders, we employ 10,000 agents. A larger population means increased model stability and reduced sensitivity to random issues. The presence of substantially more artificial agents creates a competitive environment where different trading rules compete and evolve in parallel at the same time. Having a greater number of agents opens up the opportunity to implement a wider variety of trading strategies programmed in the agents’ trading rules [11]. – Rather than using a fixed intrinsic value of the stock (fixed at 100 in Chen and Yeh’s model), we feed the software with real historical asset prices. This is done in order to prevent the formation and development of herding behaviour by design. Cipriani and Guarino [12] argue that, when the price is fixed, individuals tend to disregard their own information and strictly follow the decisions made by the previous agents, resulting in herding behaviour. – Our model developed within Altreva settings is built incrementally (walk-forward with no overfitting of historical data). It constantly evolves and adapts to market changes instead of being static. We have 10,000 different trading strategies competing simultaneously and evolving on the artificial stock market in real time. Hence, the model is more resilient to changing market conditions, and model performance is significantly more consistent and reliable [11]. No known study examines the heterogeneity, efficiency, and behaviour of the stock market by the implementation of Strongly Typed Genetic Programming (STGP) technique. Specifically, the major contributions of this article are as follows. • Initially, to provide evidence of the emergent properties of herding behaviour, stock market efficiency, and stylised facts of financial returns gained by implementing a special form of Genetic Programming—STGP. • Secondly, to provide unique tests of the MTH within artificial stock market settings. The structure of this paper is organised as follows. Section 2 presents the experimental design of our artificial stock market. Section 3 discusses the three questions listed above. Section 4 concludes the paper.
نتیجه گیری انگلیسی
This paper investigates and analyses the behavioural foundations of the stylised facts of empirical data such as leptokurtosis, non-IIDness, and volatility clustering that characterise real-world financial markets. The main contribution of this article is the trade-off between reality (real historical data of the three financial instruments) and calibration of the mechanisms and processes (artificial and empirical models developed) and the explanatory power of the stylised facts analysed through STGP techniques. Our experimental results show that an artificial stock market populated by a small subset of best-performing agents behaves differently from a market with greater genetic diversity. Although there is no discernible difference in terms of volatility, the market based on the behaviour of ‘All Agents’ exhibits less herding and is more efficient than the segmented market populated by ‘Best Agents’. Hence, the price formation process caused by the collective behaviour (competition and co-evolution) of the entire market is a better predictor than any small fraction of agents. This is a result of the greater genetic diversity that is presented in the total population. Enhanced diversity means more heterogeneous trading rules and behaviour leading to greater flexibility in the virtual market clearing price mechanism. In simple economic terms this refers to an improved manner in submitting market orders, balancing supply and demand, and setting the stock prices. Also, with the presence of more traders, the market is more competitive, and more of the information is reflected in the order flow. In considering our results, one might draw an analogy with the situation in many physical systems where the state of the system at given time is dependent on previous states and on random noise (for example, an AR(1) or red noise system, where x(t+1)=rx(1)x(t)+ε(t)x(t+1)=rx(1)x(t)+ε(t), with rx(1)rx(1) being the autocorrelation function at lag 1 and ε(t)ε(t) being random noise). A high level of random noise can act to dampen the situation where the system goes out of control, with high values of xx being amplified through time. In our case, having a large number of agents with different attributes acts to dampen excessive herding. In this particular case, we find no support for the Marginal Trader Hypothesis which holds that a small group of traders such as ‘Best Agents’ keep an asset’s market price equal to its fundamental value and steer markets to efficient levels. Moreover, in line with previous research, there is some evidence of more herding in a group of stocks than in individual stocks, but even there the magnitude of herding is far from dramatic and does not exhibit the long-run mispricing of assets and bubble formation. There is no consensus about the presence of asset price bubbles. Most academics argue that all historical bubbles can be described by fundamentally justified expectations related to the future returns on the respective underlying asset. We found evidence to support this claim, because herding behaviour detected in our experiments cannot be classified as being excessive. Greater genetic diversity (‘All Agents’ groups) also means less nonlinear dependence, more unpredictability, and therefore an enhanced level of randomness in the return series. Hence, these series can be considered more efficient. Unlike small groups of artificial agents, where substantial volatility clustering persists, the presence of more agents has led the market to lower levels of localised bursts in the amplitude of price fluctuations. Our results are consistent with the findings of Caram et al. [14], who demonstrated the complex nature of the markets. The authors showed that agents of equal size are not only in market competition with those of bigger or smaller sizes, but are also in strong competition with each other at their own level. The existence of herding behaviour in financial markets represents a classic example of the need for regulatory intervention. Herding can lead to systemic risks in financial markets. For instance, investors are likely to copy what others are doing, and buy or sell what others are selling, and own what others own. Regulatory troubles caused by systemic risks are likely to occur, due to the fact that investors are rewarded by relative performance, and therefore risk-averse individuals follow the pack. From another point of view, investors are more vulnerable to be dismissed for being wrong and alone than being wrong and in company [32]. The growth of investment institutions over the years has increased the possibility of herding. For example, the percentage of the UK stock market held by individuals alone dramatically decreased from 54% in 1963 to 12.8% in 2006 [33]. Herding behaviour is more likely to occur in markets dominated by institutions, because managers employed by institutions operate in the market to make money and retain their jobs. Their performance is often based on large compensation packages. The intuition behind this claim is that the profit condition—particularly a mandate to achieve a minimum benchmark return—could lead to weaker incentives for individuals to deviate from the benchmark, and hence it effectively reduces the competition among them. The lack of competition may lead to the convergence of opinions and the adoption of similar investment strategies. Hence, herding behaviour is encouraged causing potential long-term market reverses and relaxed risk-management controls [34], [35] and [36].