مدل اندازه گیری مستقل ریسک انبوه طرز فکر ویژه
کد مقاله | سال انتشار | تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی |
---|---|---|
19557 | 2008 | 19 صفحه PDF |
Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)
Journal : Journal of Empirical Finance, Volume 15, Issue 5, December 2008, Pages 878–896
چکیده انگلیسی
This paper introduces a model-independent measure of aggregate idiosyncratic risk, which does not require estimation of market betas or correlations and is based on the concept of gain from portfolio diversification. The statistical results and graphical analyses provide strong evidence that there are significant level and trend differences between the average idiosyncratic volatility measures of Campbell et al. [Campbell, J.Y., Lettau, M., Malkiel, B.G., and Xu, Y., 2001, Have individual stocks become more volatile? An empirical exploration of idiosyncratic risk, Journal of Finance 56, 1–43.] and the new methodology. Although both approaches indicate a noticeable increase in the firm-level idiosyncratic risk, the volatility measure of CLMX is greater and has a stronger upward trend than the new idiosyncratic volatility measure. For both measures of idiosyncratic risk, the upward trend is found to be stronger for smaller, lower-priced, and younger firms. The analytical and empirical results show that the significant upward trend in the differences of the two idiosyncratic volatility measures is related to the increase in the cross-sectional dispersion of the volatility of individual stocks.
مقدمه انگلیسی
Campbell, Lettau, Malkiel and Xu (2001) (hereafter CLMX) decompose the return of an individual stock into three components to study the volatility of stock returns at the market, industry, and firm levels. CLMX use the firm-level return data to examine the volatility of the value-weighted NYSE/AMEX/Nasdaq composite index and the value-weighted average idiosyncratic volatility. Their results provide strong evidence for a positive deterministic trend in the firm-level idiosyncratic volatility for the period of July 1962 to December 1997. Schwert (1989) finds that the market volatility has no significant trend over the sample period of 1859–1987. Although there has been a strong belief that stock market volatility has increased over time CLMX confirm and update Schwert's finding that aggregate stock market volatility does not exhibit any visible upward slope from July 1962 to December 1997. CLMX conclude that the stock market has become more volatile over the sample period of 1962–1997 but on a firm level instead of a market or industry level. The trend increase in idiosyncratic volatility relative to market volatility implies that the correlations among individual stock returns and the explanatory power of the market model for a typical stock have declined. It is also more difficult to diversify away idiosyncratic risk with a limited number of stocks in a portfolio. Xu and Malkiel (2003) decompose the total volatility of individual stocks into systematic volatility and idiosyncratic volatility and provide strong evidence that the average idiosyncratic volatility has trended upwards. They find that the increase in idiosyncratic volatility is associated with the increasing share of trading in the Nasdaq market, the degree of institutional ownership in the stock market, and the expected earnings growth of individual stocks. Irvine and Pontiff (2005) show that the upward trend in aggregate idiosyncratic risk is related to an increase in the idiosyncratic volatility of fundamental cash flows. They also argue that the rise in cash flow volatility can be explained by increasing competition in various industries. Brandt, Brav, and Graham (2005) and Bekaert, Hodrick, and Zhang (2005) cast doubts on the existence of significant upward trend in aggregate idiosyncratic volatility. They find that the positive trend is specific to the 1962–1997 sample period, and the episode of very high idiosyncratic volatility in the 1990s is limited to stocks with low institutional ownership and low stock price. Cao, Simin, and Zhao (in press) indicate that controlling for growth options eliminates or even reverses the upward trend in firm-level volatility. Brown and Kapadia (2007) show that the trend in idiosyncratic volatility is driven by new listings. Wei and Zhang (2006) provide evidence that the upward trend in idiosyncratic volatility is explained by a drop in return-on-equity and an increase in the volatility of the return-on-equity, especially in new listings. These articles indicate that firm size, price, and age are important characteristics to explain the upward trend in idiosyncratic volatility. The aforementioned studies compute the average idiosyncratic volatility based on the variance decomposition or using the residuals from the one-factor capital asset pricing model (CAPM) or three-factor model of Fama and French (1993). The excess return of an individual stock is defined in previous studies as the sum of its systematic excess return component and its idiosyncratic return component. Then, the idiosyncratic risk is measured by the variance decomposition or by factor models assuming a certain parametric specification for the return generating process. In other words, the estimation of aggregate idiosyncratic risk has so far been model-dependent. Earlier studies including Campbell et al. (2001) and Xu and Malkiel (2003) define total risk of an individual stock i as σi2 = f(M) + g(εi), where f(M) is the portion of total variance explained some model M. If the model is correct and we are fully diversified then g(εi) is irrelevant as in the CAPM. However, measuring the idiosyncratic risk by g(εi) is meaningful only if the model M is correct. If we have various models M1, M2, M3,… we end up with different measures of idiosyncratic risk for the same individual stock i. Unless we know the correct model we cannot obtain an accurate and unique measure of idiosyncratic volatility. For example, if we need to calculate the number of stocks that should be held to achieve a certain level of diversification, model-dependent measures of idiosyncratic volatility will generate different numbers. Two basic related properties implied by the CAPM are that all investors hold in their portfolio all the risky securities available in the market, and that investors hold the risky assets in the same proportions, as these assets are available in the market, independent of the investors' preference. However, these properties contradict with the market experience. First, investors differ in their investment strategy and do not necessarily adhere to the same risky portfolio. Second, the typical investor usually does not hold many risky assets in his portfolio for various reasons, such as transaction costs, incomplete information, indivisibility of investment, institutional restrictions, liquidity constraints, or any other exogenous reasons. Therefore, when calculating the number of stocks that should be held to achieve a given level of diversification it is inappropriate to use the CAPM common decomposition of the variance as it is assumed that one holds small number of stocks. In other words, using the factor or CAPM based models in estimating idiosyncratic volatility may lead to inaccurate or inconsistent measures of diversifiable risk. If investors held all the risky securities available in the market, the expected return of individual stocks would be determined solely by their contribution to the risk of the market portfolio (i.e., only systematic risk would affect expected returns). However, Blume and Friend (1975) find that the average number of securities held in a portfolio of typical investor is about 3.41. Barber and Odean (2000) report that the mean household's portfolio contains only 4.3 stocks and the median household invests in 2.61 stocks. Both studies indicate that most individuals hold very small number of stocks in their portfolios. With a constraint on the number of securities in the portfolio idiosyncratic risk becomes an important component of the investor's asset allocation decision as it affects the expected return and risk of the portfolio. Furthermore, there are several asset pricing models in the literature that take idiosyncratic risk into account. For example, Levy (1978) shows in a framework with limited diversification that the equilibrium asset pricing equation relates the returns of individual stocks to their beta with the market and their beta with respect to a market-wide measure of idiosyncratic risk. Hence, measuring and investigating the aggregate idiosyncratic risk have important implications for asset pricing models where the investors hold undiversified portfolios. This paper introduces a model-independent measure of aggregate idiosyncratic risk based on the mean-variance portfolio theory and the concept of gain from portfolio diversification. With the new approach, there is no need to estimate the covariance terms or the industry-level or firm-level beta coefficients when constructing the average idiosyncratic risk at the industry- or firm-level. Since there is no gain from diversification when the correlations among individual stocks equal one, the variance of the portfolio with perfectly correlated securities contains systematic risk and idiosyncratic risk of the securities in the portfolio.3 We also think that the stock market index can be viewed as a fully diversified portfolio, which does not contain any idiosyncratic risk. Since the market portfolio contains a large number of stocks, enough diversification gains are achieved and the idiosyncratic risk contributes nothing to the total risk of the market portfolio. That is, the risk of this well-diversified portfolio is due solely to the systematic risk of the securities in the portfolio. The new measure of average idiosyncratic volatility is defined as the difference between the variance of the non-diversified portfolio and the variance of the fully diversified portfolio. We present two versions of the new methodology; one decomposing total risk into firm and market variance, and the other decomposing total risk into firm, industry, and market variance. Although the average idiosyncratic volatility measures of CLMX and the new methodology have very similar fluctuations through time, there are some significant differences. Similar to the findings of CLMX and Xu and Malkiel, we detect a significant increase in the average firm-level idiosyncratic volatility for the NYSE/AMEX/Nasdaq stocks. The statistical results and graphical analyses from the new approach decomposing total risk into firm and market variance, and decomposing total risk into firm, industry, and market variance indicate that the average idiosyncratic volatility has trended upwards for the whole sample, but the trend is more pronounced for the Nasdaq stocks and relatively weaker for the NYSE/AMEX and NYSE sample. The results from testing the differences in means, medians, and variances and the graphical analyses provide strong evidence that there are significant level and trend differences between the average idiosyncratic volatility measures of CLMX and the new methodology. It will be shown both theoretically and empirically that the value-weighted average idiosyncratic variances estimated with the CLMX methodology are greater than those of the new methodology. The upward trend in the new idiosyncratic volatility measure is not as strong as in the idiosyncratic volatility measure of CLMX. The level and trend differences are more noticeable for the Nasdaq stocks, but the differences are rather weak for the NYSE/AMEX and NYSE sample. These results hold for the sample period of CLMX (1962:07-1997:12) and for the extended sample period of 1962:07-2005:12. We show both analytically and empirically that the differences between the idiosyncratic volatility measures of CLMX and new methodology are more significant when the cross-sectional dispersion in the standard deviation of individual stocks is larger. Since there is an increase in the cross-sectional dispersion of the volatility of individual stocks through time we find an upward trend in the differences of the two aggregate idiosyncratic volatility measures. A notable point is that there is a significant time trend in the cross-sectional dispersion of the standard deviation (and variance) of the NYSE/AMEX/Nasdaq and Nasdaq stocks for both sample periods. However, the plots for the NYSE/AMEX and NYSE sample do not exhibit such a strong upward slope. We also investigate the significance of trend in idiosyncratic volatility for a group of stocks formed based on firm size, price, and age. Specifically, we test the presence and significance of trend in aggregate idiosyncratic volatility of large, small, high-priced, low-priced, young, and old firms. The statistical results indicate that the upward trend in idiosyncratic volatility is stronger for smaller, lower-priced, and younger firms. This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces alternative measures of aggregate idiosyncratic risk. Section 3 describes the data and estimation methodology. Section 4 presents the empirical findings for groups of stocks based on the exchange. Section 5 provides results for groups of stocks based on market capitalization, price, and firm age. Section 6 concludes the paper.
نتیجه گیری انگلیسی
This paper introduces a new measure of aggregate idiosyncratic risk based on the mean-variance portfolio theory and the concept of gain from portfolio diversification. The crucial difference between the newand existing idiosyncratic volatility measures is that the new measure does not depend on any parametric specifications of the return generating process such as the market model or the one-factor or three-factor capital asset pricing model. Therefore, with the new approach the estimation of industryand firm-level beta coefficients or correlations can be avoided when constructing the average idiosyncratic volatility at the industry and firm level. This model-independent measure of idiosyncratic risk is defined as the difference between the variances of the non-diversified and fully diversified portfolios. Two versions of the new methodology are presented in the paper: one decomposing total risk into firm and market variance, and the other decomposing total risk into firm, industry, and market variance. The idiosyncratic volatility measure proposed in the paper is compared with the idiosyncratic volatility measure of CLMX. Based on the mean and median values, the average idiosyncratic variances of stocks estimated with the CLMX methodology are greater than those calculated with the new methodology. The maximum and minimum values of the idiosyncratic variance measures of CLMX are also greater than those of the new methodology. The aggregate idiosyncratic variances of CLMX are more volatile than the new idiosyncratic variance measures. There is no significant difference in the skewness, kurtosis, autocorrelation, and ADF unit root test statistics of the volatility measures of CLMX and the new methodology. These results are robust across different groups of stocks traded on the NYSE/AMEX/Nasdaq, NYSE/AMEX, NYSE, and Nasdaq. The statistical results and graphical analyses obtained from the existing and new approaches indicate that the average idiosyncratic volatility has trended upwards for the whole sample, but the trend is more pronounced for the Nasdaq stocks and relatively weaker for the NYSE/AMEX and NYSE sample. As discussed by CLMX, these results indicate that correlations among individual stocks and the explanatory power of the market model for a typical stock have decreased over time. The increased idiosyncratic volatility also implies that the number of stocks to achieve a given level of portfolio diversification has increased. The empirical findings provide evidence that there are significant level and trend differences between the average idiosyncratic volatility measures of CLMX and the new methodology. The upward trend in the new idiosyncratic volatility measure is not as strong as in the volatility measure of CLMX. The level and trend differences are more noticeable for the Nasdaq stocks, but rather weak for the NYSE/AMEX and NYSE sample. These results hold for the sample period of CLMX and for the extended sample period of 1962:07–2005:12. We show both theoretically and empirically that the differences in the idiosyncratic volatility measures are more significant when the cross-sectional dispersion in the standard deviation of individual stocks is larger. Since there is an increase in the cross-sectional dispersion of the volatility of individual stocks through time, we find an upward trend in the differences of the two aggregate idiosyncratic volatility measures. A notable point is that there is a significant time trend in the cross-sectional dispersion of the monthly volatilities of Nasdaq stocks for both sample periods. However, the plots for the NYSE/ AMEX and NYSE sample do not exhibit such a strong upward slope. The paper also investigates the effect of firm size, price, and age on the significance of time trend in idiosyncratic volatility. Specifically, we test the presence and significance of time trend in aggregate idiosyncratic volatility of large, small, high-priced, low-priced, young, and old firms. For both the CLMX and new measures of idiosyncratic risk, the statistical results indicate that the upward trend is much stronger for smaller, lower-priced, and younger firms.