دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 10954
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

تمایلات سرمایه گذار منطقی در یک بازی تصادفی مکرر با نظارت ناقص

عنوان انگلیسی
Rational investor sentiment in a repeated stochastic game with imperfect monitoring
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
10954 2010 36 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Volume 76, Issue 3, December 2010, Pages 669–704

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
بازی های هماهنگی - انتخاب تعادل رفتاری - بازارهای دارایی تجربی - امور مالی رفتاری - تمایلات سرمایه - تجزیه و تحلیل فنی -
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Coordination games,Behavioral equilibrium selection,Experimental asset markets,Behavioral finance,Investor sentiment,Technical analysis
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  تمایلات سرمایه گذار منطقی در یک بازی تصادفی مکرر با نظارت ناقص

چکیده انگلیسی

We consider a repeated stochastic coordination game with imperfect public monitoring. In the game any pattern of coordinated play is a perfect Bayesian Nash equilibrium. Moreover, standard equilibrium selection arguments either have no bite or they select an equilibrium that is not observed in actual plays of the game. We give experimental evidence for a unique equilibrium selection and explain this very robust finding by equilibrium selection based on behavioral arguments, in particular focal point analysis, probability matching and overconfidence. Our results have interesting applications in finance because the observed equilibrium exhibits momentum, reversal and excess volatility. Moreover, the results may help to explain why technical analysis is a commonly observed investment style.

مقدمه انگلیسی

Ninety percent of what we do is based on perception. It doesn’t matter if that perception is right or wrong or real. It only matters that other people in the market believe it. I may know it’s crazy, I may think it’s wrong. But I lose my shirt by ignoring it. “Making Book on the Buck” Wall Street Journal, Sept. 23, 1988, p. 17 Real life abounds with situations where people do best, individually and collectively, by coordinating their actions: communication is only possible if we speak the same language, living together in families, cities or countries is hindered if we do not obey the same rules of conduct, software would be extremely costly to develop if everyone were using a different computer platform, and trading is facilitated if it takes place at common market places or exchanges. A case in which coordination is of particular importance is a financial market. Assuming that investors do not hold assets till maturity, there is a natural incentive to buy those assets that other investors would also buy so that one can sell them with capital gains. In all these cases there are several ways in which people could potentially coordinate (rules, norms, technology standards, etc.), so the coordination problem is non-trivial even though there is no conflict of interest. Such problems can be modelled as coordination games, where each player has the same number of strategies and there are multiple, typically Pareto-ranked equilibria. Equilibrium behavior in a coordination game requires that each player correctly anticipates the equilibrium the other players are aiming at, which seems difficult to achieve in a one-shot interaction. By contrast, in repeated interaction it may be possible to learn to coordinate on one equilibrium over time if each player observes the past actions of others. However, in reality an individual often only observes a noisy signal about what others have done in the past, and this may seriously impede the learning process. An investor, for example, can profit in the short-run if she invests according to the average expectation in the market. However, if she only observes asset prices which do not reveal individual trades she may get a very diffuse view of the average expectations of traders in the market. For these reasons we consider a game where coordination is impeded by the fact that players observe only their own payoffs and these payoffs merely provide a noisy signal about the actions chosen by others. Hence, players can never verify whether coordination has been achieved in the past and therefore cannot simply repeat the successful action in the future. Our game is a simple majority game with a finite number of strategic players who can choose between two actions, u and d. A player receives a positive payoff if her choice matches the majority and a zero payoff otherwise. The majority choice, however, is determined not only by the actions of the strategic players but also by noise, which randomly adds weight to u or d and which can overrule the strategic players with a small probability. Each player observes only the choice of the majority, while the individual actions of the other strategic players and the noise remain hidden. Hence, the game is an example of a stochastic coordination game with imperfect public monitoring (see Abreu et al., 1990). Any pattern of coordinated play is a perfect Bayesian Nash equilibrium of the repeated game, so the problem of equilibrium selection is severe. Standard dynamic models of learning, adaptive play or evolution1 have no bite here since all pure strategy equilibria of the stage game are strict and payoff equivalent. To our knowledge the tracing procedure of Harsanyi and Selten (1988) is the only equilibrium selection theory that gives a reasonably narrow (and even unique) prediction for our game. Their procedure selects the inefficient equilibrium with random behavior (in each period all players mix between u and d with equal probability). This equilibrium, however, is not observed in actual plays of the game. Indeed we are able to give robust experimental evidence for a different unique equilibrium selection. In this equilibrium the strategic players simply choose the previous period’s outcome as their action. We call this equilibrium the “switch” equilibrium because actual play is coordinated on u or d until the noise overrules the strategic players and everybody switches to the other action. We explain this very robust finding by equilibrium selection based on behavioral arguments, in particular focal point analysis, probability matching and overconfidence. While a contribution to behavioral equilibrium selection may itself be of interest for game theory, we are interested in this simple game also for its application to financial markets, which we used for the framing of the laboratory experiment. Imagine that, when a player chooses u (d), he initiates an order to buy (sell) one unit of an asset. Then the strategic players may be interpreted as managers of mutual funds, pension funds or hedge funds, while the noise is representing actions exogeneous to the coordination game like the dividends paid by firms or the buying and selling of traders that is not related to rational investing. Indeed the payoff function of our game matches the reward function of those managers. In every period they are assessed in terms of the gains/losses resulting from the actions they have taken in that period. If the manager decides to buy (sell) and prices go up (down) in this period, she will get a positive reward. Otherwise she will get a lower reward. The actual price movement reflected in the majority rule then is a simple version of the law of demand and supply. Keeping up the analogy to a coordination game, our paper shows that some of the main mechanisms underlying excess volatility, short-term momentum and long-term reversal2 can be explained as the outcome of a repeated beauty contest with noise. Indeed the “switch” equilibrium has all these features. The volatility (measured in terms of variance) of prices is higher than that of the exogenous noise (given by the die), there are phases in which prices continue in the same direction, and every now and then prices change their direction, reverting to the long-term average. Note that our model explains these upwards and downwards trends of asset markets, commonly called “investor sentiment”, as a perfect Bayesian Nash equilibrium. That is to say, we give a rational explanation of investor sentiment. In particular, in contrast to Barberis et al. (1998), the traders in our model have no misperceptions about the statistical distribution of the exogenous random process. The results of our simple game may help to explain why technical analysis is a commonly observed investment style. In contrast to the efficient market hypothesis put forward by Fama (1970), in the game considered here prices have information content as they are a signal for the achieved coordination in the market. Indeed, in the switch equilibrium the players understand this signal and base their trading on past prices. Our paper relates to a large theoretical and experimental literature on coordination games. A well-known equilibrium selection theory is the one by Harsanyi and Selten (1988). Their theory is based on two criteria, payoff dominance and risk dominance. If these criteria have opposite implications, then Harsanyi and Selten (1988), as well as Anderlini (1990), favor payoff dominance, referring to the assumption of collective rationality. However, there is no general consensus on this issue. In Carlsson and van Damme (1993) and Harsanyi (1995) the risk-dominant equilibrium is selected for. Many experimental studies examine cases where predictions based on payoff and risk dominance conflict.3 The major conclusion from these experiments is that the equilibrium selection depends on pre-play communication, the number of players, the time horizon and the structure of the interaction. The coordination problem is most severe when players are indifferent between all pure strategy equilibria of the stage game as is the case for the game in this paper. Crawford and Haller (1990) have characterized optimal strategies in repeated play of these pure coordination games. The strategies are such that players randomize in early stages of the game until they happen to achieve coordination in some stage. From that stage on players can maintain coordination forever since the actions of the precedent are now focal for everyone (cf. Schelling, 1960). As we have argued above, such strategies cannot be applied in our context of imperfect monitoring. The experiment closest to ours is Hommes et al. (2005) who have studied expectation formation in an asset market game which is similar to the one we consider in this paper. In their experiment agents also have to predict the future price of an asset, but they have no information about how the equilibrium price is determined given the agents’ forecasts, which makes it difficult to compare the experimental results with some rational benchmark. In accordance with our result Hommes et al. find that subjects coordinate on a common prediction strategy within each group. However, the observed prediction strategy varies widely across groups. The outline of the paper is the following. In Section 2 we give a formal description of the game considered in this paper. Thereafter, in Section 3, we present the results from a laboratory experiment. Section 4 explains the equilibrium selection observed in the experiment. In Section 5 we discuss the analogy of our experiment to the stock market. Section 6 concludes.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

We have studied a repeated stochastic coordination game with imperfect public monitoring. In this game any pattern of coordinated play is a perfect Bayesian Nash equilibrium. Moreover, standard equilibrium selection arguments either have no bite or they select an equilibrium that is not observed in actual play of the game. We gave experimental evidence for a unique equilibrium selection in this game and explained this very robust finding by equilibrium selection based on behavioral arguments, in particular focal point analysis, probability matching and overconfidence. Our results have interesting applications in finance because the observed equilibrium price process exhibits momentum, reversal and excess volatility. Indeed the behavioral arguments that we employed in the stylized asset market we considered are all well known from the behavioral finance literature (cf. Shefrin, 2000, Shiller, 1981, Shleifer, 2000 and Barberis and Thaler, 2003). The behavioral finance literature has attributed large increases in investment activity on stock markets to the greater fool theory, i.e. to the idea that investors believe other investors are still willing to buy their stock at a higher price. This is a clear sign of overconfidence since it is impossible for the majority of investors to be on the winning side of this speculation. Moreover, the large amount of trading activity exhibited by the average investor is attributed in this literature to probability matching, i.e. to the desire to employ a trading strategy that somehow matches the frequent ups and downs of the random process one is trying to master. As Shefrin (2000) has shown, for most traders a stolid buy&hold strategy would have obtained much better results for their investments. Finally, observed asset prices are a focal point in the search for signals revealing which information the other investors have at a time. Indeed, as Treynor and Ferguson (1985) have argued, technical analysis can be profitable due to the information it may reveal about the other traders’ state of information. Of course, a real stock market is much more complex than the stylized asset market we considered in this paper. But on the other hand our much simpler setting has the advantage of being able to demonstrate more cleanly the role of focal point analysis, probability matching and overconfidence in the coordination of investors’ actions on asset markets, that is shown to lead to momentum, reversal and excess volatility in asset prices. Further research will have to enrich our simple model with more realistic features like a dividend process with asymmetric information on the part of the investors.