دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 9878
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

استراتژی های سرمایه گذاری فعال

عنوان انگلیسی
Reactive investment strategies
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
9878 2011 11 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, Volume 49, Issue 1, July 2011, Pages 89–99

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
تخصیص دارایی پویا - چرخه سرمایه گذاری - صندوق تاریخ هدف - تخصیص دارایی - بهینه سازی پویا - حساب دیفرانسیل و انتگرال تغییرات
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  استراتژی های سرمایه گذاری فعال

چکیده انگلیسی

Asset liability management is a key aspect of the operation of all financial institutions. In this endeavor, asset allocation is considered the most important element of investment management. Asset allocation strategies may be static, and as such are usually assessed under asset models of various degrees of complexity and sophistication. In recent years attention has turned to dynamic strategies, which promise to control risk more effectively. In this paper we present a new class of dynamic asset strategy, which respond to actual events. Hence they are referred to as ‘reactive’ strategies. They cannot be characterized as a series of specific asset allocations over time, but comprise rules for determining such allocations as the world evolves. Though they depend on how asset returns and other financial variables are modeled, they are otherwise objective in nature. The resulting strategies are optimal, in the sense that they can be shown to outperform all other strategies of their type when no asset allocation constraints are imposed. Where such constraints are imposed, the strategies may be demonstrated to be almost optimal, and dramatically more effective than static strategies.

مقدمه انگلیسی

Asset allocation strategies are generally of three types: (a) Fixed asset allocations through time (typically 70% equity and 30% debt for long term investors, such as pension funds). This allocation is reviewed infrequently. (b)Asset allocations that evolve over time according to a fixed and pre-determined schedule. Examples are so-called ‘lifecycle’ funds for superannuation investors. These have a fixed horizon and generally become more defensive as an investor approaches retirement. (c)Rebalancing rules, under which the allocation at any future time is not pre-determined, but varies according to the actual investment experience up to that time. Strategies (a) and (b) have been the most commonly used in practice. However in recent years, attention has focused on (c), which are potentially effective in controlling risk. Generally an investment portfolio can drift from its target asset allocation, acquiring risk and return characteristics that may be inconsistent with an investor’s goals and preferences. A rebalancing strategy addresses this situation by formalizing guidelines about how frequently the portfolio should be monitored, how far an asset allocation can deviate from its target before it is rebalanced, and whether periodic rebalancing should restore a portfolio to its target or to some other allocation. The question is: ‘is there is an optimal rebalancing strategy in any sense?’. This is clearly a multi-period issue, formulated in either discrete or continuous time. There is a wealth of literature on how risk factors and asset classes can be modeled under approach (a). We mention only a few of them here. Martinelli (2006) provides a formal but simplified model of assets and liabilities, identifying factors which are common to them both. Using stochastic optimization, this framework leads to appropriate asset allocations which support the investor’s funding objectives. Dempster et al. (2009) adopt an econometric model covering a variety of economic, financial and asset return variables, with complex interactions between them. These are more than adequate in capturing the effect of the risk factors that drive most liabilities in practice. When coupled with investor objectives as to funding levels, an optimal asset allocation strategy may be formulated by dynamic stochastic programming, i.e. by optimization over simulated outcomes. Dhaene et al. (2005) avoid the use of simulation by approximating the copula of the dependent variables with a comonotonic copula. They do so under a lognormal framework for asset returns, employing a comonotonic copula to derive upper and lower bounds for the distribution of accumulated outcomes. More recently,Van Weert et al. (2010) extends these results to situations where cash flows are unrestricted in sign, thereby allowing savings towards pension benefits to be investigated. More recently, Li et al. (2006) also employ optimization to derive a closed form solution for the constant rebalanced portfolio (CRP—i.e. a static asset allocation) where the risk measure is based on a tail-VaR. One of the earliest implementations of type (b) was due to Cariño et al. (2006). This study is focused on maximizing terminal outcomes for an income-paying insurance product subject to a host of regulatory constraints. The solutions are reached via stochastic dynamic programming. More theoretical approaches are employed in Gerber and Shiu (2000) to obtain exact solutions under a two-asset model, with various forms of the utility of terminal outcomes. Munk (2008) provides a comprehensive review of dynamic asset strategies under various types of asset model and investor objectives. Cairns et al. (2006) provide a lifetime approach to saving for providing retirement income. Bruynel (2005) applies these techniques to a variety of situations, using a simple Markovitz model for asset returns. Most recently Huang and Lee (2010) apply this technique to the management of a life insurance portfolio where asset returns are subject to an autoregressive process. The asset strategies of type (b) are dynamic in the sense that they change over time. These naturally lead to ‘lifecycle’ or ‘target date’ savings products, where the asset allocation evolves over the lifetime of the investor. However they do so in a pre-determined way, and that might explain the limited popularity they have enjoyed in practice in some countries. Basu and Drew (2009) contest the viability of lifecycle funds which become more defensive towards the end of the investor’s horizon. They show empirically that this defensiveness is costly in terms of overall return, especially where funding is weighted towards the end of the investor’s horizon. More recently they suggest a dynamic strategy (Basu et al., 2011), where the weighting to growth assets depends on the actual performance relative to a target. Their suggestion is thus for a strategy of type (c). The alternative approach under (c) is responsive to how the asset strategy performs in practice. This may allay some concerns of the investor that he is locked into an inflexible, and possibly destructive, path. Seth (2002) takes up the issue of dynamic rebalancing to a target asset allocation. As a result of transaction costs, it is more effective to establish an asset allocation range for rebalancing, rather than rebalancing precisely to the target. Tokat and Wicas (2007) suggest that the frequency of rebalancing should depend on the direction of markets as well as on the target allocation adopted. Bone and Goddard (2009) take up this theme in the context of funding pension liabilities. A contrarian rule is one of weighting to growth assets when pension funding is poor, and vice versa. Under the contrarian rebalancing strategy, a target performance might be set as, say, 3% pa. above annual inflation. Any surplus relative to the target will be invested into bonds, while any deficiency will be invested into equities. This may be contrasted with the CRP approach, where a portfolio is rebalanced to a predetermined asset allocation. They demonstrate that both on a historical, as well as on a prospective, basis this type of strategy can be superior to a static CRP of type (a). It is certainly superior to one of a ‘casino’ type, where more is allocated to growth assets when pension funding is favorable. The apparent success of type (c) strategies is intriguing. In this paper we demonstrate that this success is not accidental, under a variety of conditions. We specifically derive the optimality criterion, and illustrate its outcomes, even in the presence of complex regulatory constraints. This is provided in the generic context of an investor with deterministic cash flows, but may be generalized to institutional investors with uncertain liabilities. Nonetheless, the need for an appropriate asset model, and identification of appropriate investor objectives, remain fundamental to all these problems.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

This paper provides a quantitative demonstration of the benefits of reactive strategies of type (c) for both iid and autoregressive asset models. It also provides a general rule for deriving such strategies, which are effective under various constraints. The calculus of variations is a key tool in this development. The analysis is much more intensely computational in the case of autoregressive models, due to the lack of a single efficient frontier. The modeling is more sensitive to the cash flows assumed with this type of model. This suggests that reactive strategies should be designed to be specific to both the term of the investment as well as the timing of a cash flow. This analysis may be generalized in several directions. First, liability models may be integrated with the asset models considered. Second, more general asset models may be considered, particularly those involving stochastic volatility, or non-independence in the innovations appearing in (12).