دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 17859
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

ریسک شکایت های قانونی، افشای استراتژیک و قیمت گذاری عرضه اولیه عمومی

عنوان انگلیسی
Litigation risk, strategic disclosure and the underpricing of initial public offerings
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
17859 2012 20 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Journal of Financial Economics, Volume 103, Issue 2, February 2012, Pages 235–254

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
ریسک شکایت های قانونی - عرضه اولیه عمومی - بازده اولیه - تعدیل جزئی - افشای استراتژیک
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Litigation risk, Initial public offerings, Initial returns, Partial adjustment, Strategic disclosure,
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  ریسک شکایت های قانونی، افشای استراتژیک و قیمت گذاری عرضه اولیه عمومی

چکیده انگلیسی

Using word content analysis on the time-series of IPO prospectuses, we show that issuers tradeoff underpricing and strategic disclosure as potential hedges against litigation risk. This tradeoff explains a significant fraction of the variation in prospectus revision patterns, IPO underpricing, the partial adjustment phenomenon, and litigation outcomes. We find that strong disclosure is an effective hedge against all types of lawsuits. Underpricing, however, is an effective hedge only against Section 11 lawsuits, those lawsuits which are most damaging to the underwriter. Underwriters who fail to adequately hedge litigation risk experience economically large penalties, including loss of market share.

مقدمه انگلیسی

When proposed by Tinic (1988) and Hughes and Thakor (1992) as a potential explanation for underpricing in initial public offerings (IPOs), litigation risk seemed both intuitively plausible and economically relevant. Section 11 of the Securities Act of 1933 gives investors the right to sue issuers and underwriters for declines in value below the offer price due to material omissions in the prospectus.1 Given the inherent uncertainty of an IPO, and the potential reputational losses associated with litigation, issuers and underwriters concerned about lawsuits can attempt to hedge litigation risk by underpricing. Drake and Vetsuypens (1993), in the first empirical paper to study the effect of litigation risk, examine differences in initial returns between IPOs that are sued and those that are not. The authors find no evidence that underpricing reduces the incidence of a lawsuit. Lowry and Shu (2002), however, take into account the endogeneity of initial returns and lawsuit incidence and find support for both an insurance and a deterrence effect as predicted by litigation risk theories. Despite this recent support, some researchers remain skeptical. Ritter and Welch (2002), in their review article state, “In our opinion, leaving money on the table appears to be a cost-ineffective way of avoiding lawsuits.” This paper proposes an enriched litigation risk framework that can reconcile these disparate views. The underlying assumption in existing studies of litigation risk is that stock market losses alone are sufficient to extract legal penalties. In reality, two conditions must be met. First, investors must have suffered damages in the form of investment losses. Second, investors must be able to produce evidence of a material omission in the firm's disclosure that existed at the time of their initial investment. Importantly, in our enriched litigation framework, plaintiffs must establish evidence of both losses and poor disclosure (an “and” not an “or” condition). To reduce litigation risk, therefore, issuers need to hedge only one of these conditions. Hedging can be done by either underpricing (to reduce damages) or by enhancing disclosure (to reduce the probability of a material omission). Our approach differs from prior studies of litigation risk in IPOs in that we examine both the firm's disclosure and pricing strategy. We hypothesize that disclosure and underpricing are substitute hedges against liability risk. In our enriched litigation framework, underpricing should be high only when a firm has a potential material omission (and vice versa). In other words, not all issuing firms will choose to use underpricing as a hedge. Therefore, the effect of underpricing in reducing incidences of litigation will be concentrated only in firms with a high probability of a material omission. One reason why this enriched litigation risk framework has not yet been tested is that a “material omission” in a firm's prospectus is difficult to measure. With the advent of textual analysis, determining a firm's disclosure strategy is now feasible. We determine the likelihood of a material omission by examining how the issuing firm reacts to the arrival of new information during the offering period. In particular, we examine the intensity of revisions to the issuer's prospectus text over the same time interval as information-gathering activities, such as bookbuilding and road shows, are being conducted. These activities often result in information material enough to generate large price revisions from the initial filing range to the final IPO price. The typical issuer files an initial prospectus and two to three revisions during the roughly three-month period between the initial filing and the IPO date, giving us considerable power to assess any changes in disclosure over time. We construct a proxy for the likelihood of a material omission in the prospectus using two conditions: (A) the extent to which the IPO price is revised since the initial filing estimate, and (B) whether the initial prospectus is not substantially revised during the offering period. Condition (A) reveals the potential materiality of the new price-relevant information that arrived during the bookbuilding process. If condition (A) is sufficiently large, condition (B) reveals that this new information was not disclosed in the prospectus, resulting in a potential material omission. Specifically, we predict that the substitution effect of pricing for disclosure is increasing in the probability of a material omission. In this context, larger price revisions indicate that the new information is particularly relevant in determining the firm's offer price, and we consider it more “material.” As a result, an issuer who chooses not to revise their disclosure following a large price revision is particularly prone to successful litigation should the stock price decline ex post. We find strong support for a substitution of pricing for disclosure as a hedge against litigation risk. The strongest substitution effect occurs when the proprietary value of the revealed information is likely to be high, i.e., in IPOs with positive price-relevant information generated during the offering period. The economic magnitude of these initial returns is substantial and is even larger still for issuers with high ex ante litigation risk. Ex ante litigation risk is determined by how similar the issuer's prospectus is to IPOs that were sued prior to the issuer's filing date. Thus, litigation risk plays an important role in the partial adjustment phenomenon and can explain why the underpricing of IPOs with positive information “seems too large to be explained as equilibrium compensation for revealing favorable information” (Ritter and Welch, 2002). The traditional interpretation of the litigation risk theory is that high underpricing can deter all lawsuits by reducing damages. But underpricing applies only to IPO purchasers and therefore, cannot deter lawsuits brought by aftermarket purchasers. In our enriched litigation framework, we propose and test an alternative view of the deterrence effect of initial returns. We show that the deterrence effect of underpricing is in reducing the probability that IPO investors will bring a lawsuit under Section 11. We find that the primary benefit of deterring a Section 11 lawsuit is to reduce the likelihood of the underwriter being named in the suit and suffering reputational damage along with subsequent market share losses.2 The risk of being named in a lawsuit and losing market share can explain why underwriters are willing to substantially underprice even when positive information is revealed. Unlike initial returns, we show that enhanced disclosure can deter all types of lawsuits because it applies equally to both IPO investors and aftermarket purchasers. However, disclosure can be a more costly mechanism to hedge litigation risk than underpricing if the new information has high proprietary value to the issuing firm. Our findings contribute to the ongoing debate regarding the role of voluntary disclosure in shareholder litigation (e.g., Francis, Philbrick, and Schipper, 1994; Evans and Sridhar, 2002; Field, Lowry, and Shu, 2005; Rogers and Buskirk, 2009 and Lowry, 2009). While much of this literature has found that bad information is withheld and good information is disclosed (for example, Skinner, 1994, Skinner, 1997 and Healy and Palepu, 2001), we find the opposite to be true. We suggest that this conflicting finding is likely due to differences in incentives (Kothari, Shu, and Wysocki, 2009) and the regulatory environment surrounding the IPO process. Finally, our paper adds to a growing body of work that uses word content analysis to analyze the informativeness of written disclosure. In the context of managing litigation risk, Nelson and Pritchard (2008), Mohan (2007), and Rogers, Buskirk, and Zechman (2010) find that certain word usage is related to the probability of being sued. Hanley and Hoberg (2010) examine the information content of IPO initial prospectuses and its effect on pricing. Hoberg and Phillips (2010) use text similarity analysis to test theories of merger incidence and outcomes. Loughran and McDonald (2010) show that firms using Plain English have greater small-investor participation and shareholder-friendly corporate governance. In other contexts, papers such as Antweiler and Frank (2004), Tetlock (2007), Tetlock, Saar-Tsechanksy, and Macskassy (2008), Li (2006), Boukus and Rosenberg (2006), and Loughran and McDonald (2011) find word content to be informative in predicting stock price movements. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: A brief discussion of the incentive to withhold or disclose information learned during bookbuilding is presented in Section 2. The data, word vector construction method, and summary statistics are in Section 3. Our method of classifying disclosure strategy is discussed in Section 4. The relation of disclosure strategy and litigation risk to initial returns (the insurance effect) is in Section 5. How disclosure strategy and initial returns affect the probability of a lawsuit (the deterrence effect) is in Section 6. The economic consequence of lawsuits for underwriters is explored in Section 7. The paper concludes in Section 8.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

By using word content analysis, we are able to assess the disclosure strategy of IPO firms in response to information learned during bookbuilding. Our findings suggest that prior empirical findings place too much reliance on underpricing as a hedge against litigation risk. We show that disclosure and underpricing act as substitutes in hedging litigation risk, and only firms with a high risk of a material omission are likely to use initial returns as a hedge against lawsuits. We also show an asymmetric response to information learned during the offering process. IPOs with good information revealed during bookbuilding have an incentive to withhold information for proprietary reasons and be subject to a material omission. Because, in this case, proceeds are greater than expected, the firm has pricing flexibility and underpricing is potentially “cheaper” as a hedge against lawsuits. Conversely, there is little benefit to withholding bad information as it has lower proprietary value to rivals and is difficult to conceal for any length of time. Under this scenario, proceeds are lower than expected, underpricing is “expensive,” and these firms are more likely to use disclosure rather than underpricing to hedge litigation risk. We show that these relationships are more pronounced when the firm faces greater ex ante litigation risk. Consistent with the existing literature, we find an insurance effect in initial returns in which greater underpricing is associated with greater ex ante litigation risk, but our findings differ in two ways. First, we show that disclosure during bookbuilding has a strong deterrence effect against all types of lawsuits regardless of the type of plaintiff. Second, we find that high initial returns can deter IPO investors from bringing the lawsuit under Section 11. Thus, underpricing is a deterrent against the type of lawsuit that can most damage the underwriter, but not overall lawsuit incidence. Importantly, we find that underwriters are the primary beneficiaries of deterring Section 11 lawsuits because this deterrence limits the plaintiff's ability to name the underwriter as a defendant. Our results suggest that underwriters have a strong incentive to underprice the issue aggressively to avoid the loss of reputational capital and to prevent a subsequent decline in market share in the event of a lawsuit. Overall, our findings suggest that a good portion of the partial adjustment phenomenon can be attributed to issuer and underwriter efforts to mitigate exposure to litigation risk. In particular, partial adjustment arises as underwriters require very high levels of underpricing to preserve their reputation capital should issuers choose not to revise their prospectus after learning new information. Because these tradeoffs are based on rational economic incentives inherent to the legal system, our results provide an explanation as to why the partial adjustment phenomenon continues to be robust through time.