دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 13147
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

مقررات محیطی و سرمایه گذاری مستقیم خارجی: شواهدی از کره جنوبی

عنوان انگلیسی
Environmental Regulation and Foreign Direct Investment: Evidence from South Korea
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
13147 2014 41 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Journal of Development Economics, , In Press, Accepted Manuscript, Available online 13 January 2014

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
فرضیه پناهگاه آلودگی -      مقررات زیست محیطی -      مزیت نسبی -      سرمایه گذاری مستقیم خارجی -      کره جنوبی -
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
pollution haven hypothesis, environmental regulation, comparative advantage, foreign direct investment, South Korea,
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  مقررات محیطی و سرمایه گذاری مستقیم خارجی: شواهدی از کره جنوبی

چکیده انگلیسی

This paper studies how environmental regulation shapes the pattern of foreign direct investment (FDI), and thereby assesses the pollution haven hypothesis. Conflicting results exist in the case studies examining the most advanced countries, partly due to the deterrent effect of clean technology adoptions on industry migration. To minimize the clean technology effect, we examine the pattern of South Korean FDI over 2000–2007, the period that Korean firms relied on old production technologies despite facing rapidly strengthened environmental standards. A difference-in-differences type identification strategy circumvents other potential confounders. We find strong evidence that polluting industries tend to invest more in countries with laxer environmental regulations in terms of both the amount of investment (intensive margin) and the number of new foreign affiliates (extensive margin). A similar finding is obtained when imports are analyzed.

مقدمه انگلیسی

The fall of global economic barriers, along with technological advances, has accelerated the international fragmentation of production processes. Firms strategically relocate their production systems to foreign countries where they can benefit from country-specific advantages. This incentive is referred to as the comparative advantage (or vertical) motive for foreign direct investment (FDI). An emerging question is which country-specific characteristics generate a comparative advantage that shapes the pattern of FDI. The literature has typically focused on factor endowments, such as skilled labor and physical capital, and found evidence that countries with an abundant factor endowment attract more foreign investors in industries that use the given factor intensively (e.g., (Antràs, 2003 and Yeaple, 2003)). (See Fig. 1, Fig. 2 and Fig. 3.) Interestingly, in a separate strand of literature, the laxity of environmental regulations has also been assessed as a potential source of comparative advantage. The theoretical rationale is straightforward: polluting firms have an incentive to shift their production system to countries with lax environmental regulations to lower production costs. Classical Heckscher-Ohlin trade theory is then applied to predict that environmentally lax countries specialize in industries producing polluting goods, whereas environmentally stringent countries specialize in industries producing clean goods. 2 Unlike the factor endowments case, however, tests of this so-called pollution haven hypothesis (or pollution haven effect) have yielded rather conflicting and weak empirical evidence. (Brunnermeier & Levinson, 2004) summarize in their review that early literature up to the 1990s typically find no significant pollution haven effect, while later studies tend to find a statistically significant, but economically mild, effect of environmental regulations on industry composition. One concern in the pollution haven literature is that it has heavily relied on empirical results from the most advanced countries, such as the U.S. (Eskeland and Harrison, 2003, Grossman and Krueger, 1994 and Hanna, 2010), Germany (Wagner & Timmins, 2009), and the U.K. (Manderson & Kneller, 2012). Although these countries impose the toughest environmental standards, they also retain potential confounding factors that may dampen the pollution haven effect. A typical approach to solve the problem is to use exclusion restrictions (Kellenberg, 2009, Levinson and Taylor, 2008 and Xing and Kolstad, 2002). However, the validity of exclusion restrictions is in fact often criticized (Broner et al., 2012 and Millimet and Roy, 2011). Another group of studies tries directly to disentangle such confounders. (Antweiler et al., 2001) and (Cole & Elliott, 2005), for example, posit that polluting industries, which tend to be capital intensive, may locate in advanced countries to exploit rich capital stocks despite the countries’ stringent environmental regulations. Both studies find statistically significant pollution haven effects when this capital-seeking incentive is sorted out. In other studies, (Ederington et al., 2005) and (Wagner & Timmins, 2009) argue that positive spillovers from industry agglomeration can be an important reason for polluting firms not to leave advanced countries. Another crucial, yet overlooked, confounder is clean technology adoption. Environmental regulations may not only induce shift of production location, but also promote innovation and adoption of clean technologies (Popp et al., 2010). Firms employing clean technologies in response to the domestic environmental regulations, usually observed in the rich world, would have less incentive for outward migration. 3 In this spirit, (Dean et al., 2009) examine the pattern of FDI inflows across Chinese provinces to test whether foreign firms embodying less efficient abatement technologies are more responsive to inter-provincial differences of environmental regulations. Their finding confirms that only ethnically Chinese investors were significantly sensitive to the provincial differences, while non-ethnically Chinese investors who transferred relatively advanced technologies showed no significant response. Until now, no study examining the most advanced countries has yet addressed the clean technology issue. This paper provides new evidence for the pollution haven hypothesis by investigating the pattern of South Korean FDI outflows to 50 host countries in 121 industries over the period 2000–2007. The Korean case is an advantageous setting for the clean technology issue. After experiencing severe environmental degradation accompanied by dramatic economic growth, South Korea newly adopted and amended almost its entire body of environmental legislation throughout the 1990s (OECD, 1997). However, the adoption of clean technologies lags behind the change in regulations, as Korean firms, mostly small- and medium-sized ones, still rely on old, dirty production technologies. In the subsequent review, ( (OECD, 2006), p. 1) stresses that “indicators of carbon, energy and some material intensities still remain among the highest in the OECD.” 4 Facing increasingly stringent environmental standards with limited access to clean technologies, the incentive for Korean firms to seek a pollution haven appears clearer than those in the most advanced countries. To deal with other potential confounders, we employ a difference-in-differences (DID) type identification strategy, i.e., determinants of comparative advantage are identified by interaction terms between country and industry characteristics. 5 If environmental laxity is a determinant of comparative advantage, the pollution haven effect is identified through the interaction term between a host country’s environmental laxity (relative to home country) and industry’s pollution intensity. This approach enables us to disentangle opposing forces between environmental laxity and other determinants of comparative advantage. Furthermore, since our variables of interest are in interaction terms, we can control for all country- and industry-specific unobserved heterogeneity, in which case our model for FDI flow resembles the empirical model for trade flow used in (Romalis, 2004). Hence, we can apply the same model to trade data to see if a consistent behavior is observed in the pattern of trade. After relevant issues are carefully treated, we find strong evidence for the pollution haven hypothesis. Countries with relatively lenient environmental regulations tend to attract more South Korean FDI in polluting industries than in non-polluting industries in terms of the total amount of investment (i.e., intensive margin of FDI). Economic significance is comparable to the disproportional effects of physical capital and skill endowment. This finding is robust to the inclusion of additional sources of comparative advantage. Note that, however, the same finding disappears in such cases when (i) industries are observed at a more aggregated level, (ii) physical capital is not included as a source of comparative advantage, or (iii) unobserved heterogeneity is not adequately controlled for. This highlights the importance of an elaborate identification strategy and a fairly disaggregated data. With the same identification strategy and data, we also find that the pollution haven effect is consistently observed in the patterns of new birth of foreign affiliates (i.e., extensive margins of FDI). Polluting industries show a disproportionally higher tendency to establish their new foreign affiliates in environmentally laxer countries than non-polluting industries do. When our model is applied to South Korean import data, we find that countries with lax environmental regulations tend to specialize in the production of polluting goods and export them to Korea. Our paper contributes to the literature in a number of ways. First, the strong evidence from South Korea extends the validity of the pollution haven behavior to newly developed countries. In particular, the pollution haven incentive can be magnified in a transitional phase where clean technologies have not been adopted despite strengthened environmental regulations than in a phase where environmental regulations have already induced self-perpetuating clean technology innovation and adoption. This prediction is also in line with the recent literature on the directed technical change toward clean technology (Acemoglu et al., 2012 and Aghion et al., 2012). Secondly, even though the pollution haven hypothesis is testable by examining the pattern of FDI flow (Cole and Elliott, 2005, Eskeland and Harrison, 2003, Hanna, 2010, Javorcik and Wei, 2004 and Kellenberg, 2009), trade flow (Broner et al., 2012, Ederington et al., 2005, Grossman and Krueger, 1994 and Levinson and Taylor, 2008), or birth of plants (List et al., 2003), no study to our knowledge has looked into different types of industry activity at the same time. We investigate those three different industry activities to confirm a consistent behavior among one another and thereby provide a clearer picture of industry relocation occurring in a country. The third contribution is methodological. Our strategy is particularly useful when investigating FDI at the cross-country level, because the decision process of foreign investment is very sensitive not only to the industry structure of home countries but also to the characteristics of host countries, which generates a variety of country- and industry-level unobserved heterogeneity. 6 The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes our data and discusses some important features of the data. In Section 3, we set up empirical models and address related econometric issues. Section 4 presents estimation results with their robustness checks. Section 5 concludes.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

This paper supplements the literature on the pollution haven hypothesis by providing new evidence from a country that has rarely been explored. Specifically, we examine the pattern of South Korean outward FDI as well as imports over 2000–2007 to test whether polluting industries in Korea show differing patterns of investment according to the difference in environmental laxity between home and a host country. South Korea has rapidly strengthened environmental standards throughout the 1990s while access to clean technologies was still limited, which in turn magnified the incentive of polluting firms to consider relocating to a pollution haven. Thus, the Korean circumstance provides a good setting to put the pollution haven hypothesis to test. Our finding concludes that the laxity of environmental regulations is both a statistically and economically significant determinant of comparative advantage in FDI at both intensive and extensive margins, which supports the pollution haven hypothesis. The finding also indicates that the same pollution haven behavior consistently appears in the pattern of international trade. Note, however, that the poor treatment of data aggregation, other determinants of comparative advantage, or unobserved heterogeneity can mask the said pollution haven effect. This highlights the importance of a carefully designed empirical model with at least a fairly disaggregated industry-level data to avoid potential econometric problems. Further research is desirable to extend the validity of the pollution haven hypothesis particularly taking the effect of clean technologies into account. Since we state that the pollution haven behavior will be more clearly observed in countries with lack of clean technologies despite their high environmental standards, investigating such countries would help confirm validity. It would be also interesting to unravel in a model the underlying mechanism of how environmental policies simultaneously affect a firm’s decisions on migration and clean technology adoption. In a broader sense, this line of research is expected to deepen our understanding of the pollution haven hypothesis in relation to the economic growth process and the role of clean technologies.