دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 19973
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

اثرات چنددوره ای مسئولیت اجتماعی شرکت ها در شبکه های زنجیره تامین، هزینه های معامله، انتشار سهام، و خطر

عنوان انگلیسی
Multiperiod effects of corporate social responsibility on supply chain networks, transaction costs, emissions, and risk
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
19973 2008 14 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : International Journal of Production Economics, Volume 116, Issue 1, November 2008, Pages 61–74

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
زنجیره های تامین - محیط زیست - مسئولیت اجتماعی شرکت ها - مدیریت ریسک - شبکه تعادل - قیمت گذاری - نابرابری ورزشی - تصمیم گیری چند معیاری
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Supply chains, Environment, Corporate social responsibility, Risk management, Network equilibrium, Pricing, Variational inequalities, Multicriteria decision-making
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  اثرات چنددوره ای مسئولیت اجتماعی شرکت ها در شبکه های زنجیره تامین، هزینه های معامله، انتشار سهام، و خطر

چکیده انگلیسی

This paper develops a framework for the analysis of the optimal levels of corporate social responsibility (CSR) activities in a multiperiod supply chain network consisting of manufacturers, retailers, and consumers. Manufacturers and retailers determine their production quantities, transaction quantities, and the amount of social responsibility activities they want to pursue that maximize net return, minimize emission, and minimize risk over the planning horizon. We investigate the interplay of the heterogeneous decision-makers and compute the equilibrium pattern of product outputs, transactions, prices, and levels of social responsibility activities. The paper provides insights concerning the optimal allocation of resources to CSR activities when considering a multiperiod time frame.

مقدمه انگلیسی

Corporate social responsibility (CSR) encompasses the economic, legal, ethical, and philanthropic expectations placed on organizations by society at a given point in time (Carroll and Buchholtz, 2002). Today, CSR is not only a prominent research theme but it can also be found in corporate missions and value statements (Svendsen et al., 2001). Companies increasingly realize that their actions in purchasing and supply chain management strongly affect their reputation and long-term success (Castka and Balzarova, 2008, and references therein). Corporations are held accountable for promoting and protecting the environmental, health, and safety regulations of workers that make their products, regardless if they are direct employees or work for their suppliers. For example, corporations like Nike, Liz Claiborne, Disney, and Wal-Mart have faced damaging media reports, external pressure from activists, and internal pressure from investors demanding that companies acknowledge responsibility for labor rights abuses in factories that make their products (Arriaga, 2008). McDonalds, Mitsubishi, Monsanto, Nestle, Nike, Shell, and Texaco have suffered damage to their reputations and sales as a result of public awareness campaigns by advocacy groups about their CSR practices (Svendsen et al., 2001). As a consequence, companies start expanding their responsibility for their products beyond their sales and delivery locations (Bloemhof-Ruwaard et al., 1995) and they start managing the CSR of their partners within the supply chain (Kolk and Tudder, 2002 and Emmelhainz and Adams, 1999). Many researchers have tried to understand business motivation to adopt CSR programs (Delmas and Terlaak, 2002 and Marcus et al., 2002), legal and institutional factors shaping CSR, the effects of attitudes of managers and consumers towards CSR (Williams and Aguilera, 2008), the effects of the dissemination of industry standards such as ISO 26000 (Castka and Balzarova, 2008) and the relationship between the three concepts, CSR, risk, and profit (Dowling, 2001, Fombrun, 2001, Clarkson, 1991, Kotter and Heskett, 1992, Collins and Porras, 1995, Waddock and Graves, 1997, Berman et al., 1999 and Roman et al., 1999). Indeed, firms engage in CSR activities as a way to enhance their reputation (Fombrun, 2005), preempt legal sanction (Parker, 2002), respond to NGO action (Spar and La Mure, 2003), manage their risk (Fombrun et al., 2000 and Husted, 2005), and to generate customer loyalty (Bhattacharya and Sen, 2001 and Bhattacharya and Sen, 2004). CSR can potentially decrease production inefficiencies, reduce cost and risk and at the same time allow companies to increase sales, increase access to capital, new markets, and brand recognition. While many companies see CSR as a means for damage control or PR, companies increasingly realize that CSR activities offer opportunities to create value (Porter and Kramer, 2006). “The practice of CSR is an investment in the company's future; as such, it must be planned specifically, supervised carefully, and evaluated regularly” (Falck and Heblich, 2007, p. 248). It is very important that organizations take the long-term benefits of CSR into consideration when determining their optimal investment in CSR activities. Merck & Co. Inc. is an example of a company that benefitted from reputational capital created by CSR activities in the past (Fombrun, 1996). In 1995, Merck & Co. Inc.'s Flint River plant in Albany, New York, leaked phosphorous trichloride. As a result of the leak, 45 people were taken to hospital and 400 workers were evacuated (Svendsen et al., 2001). However, the community response ranged from indifference to laudatory support of Merck. Merck was given the benefit of the doubt because it had been a good CSR citizen (Svendsen et al., 2001). While Merck & Co. Inc. benefitted from its reputational capital, BP suffered negative financial and reputational consequences due to insufficient attention to CSR activities in the past. In 2004, BP was fined a record $1.42 million for health and safety offenses in Alaska even as the chief executive of BP was establishing himself as a leading advocate for CSR (Doane, 2005). In reality, determining the “ideal level of CSR” activities (McWilliams and Siegel, 2001) is difficult. Even more difficult, is it to set the right incentive structures into place to ensure that this level is reached since pressures for short-term performance are often very strong (Falck and Heblich, 2007). However, to plan and communicate the value of CSR activities, its long-term effects need to be better understood (Porter and Kramer, 2006). To contribute to this understanding, we build a multitiered multiperiod supply chain model where decision-makers cannot only decide about the product flows that they want to transact with each other but where they can also strategically allocate resources to CSR activities. The analysis of the model allows for insights on how CSR’ activities impact companies’ performance in the long run and how ideal levels of CSR activities are influenced by factors within as well as outside the firm. Several of the assumptions in the model are similar to the assumptions of the conceptual model by McWilliams and Siegel (2001). As in McWilliams and Siegel (2001) we assume that firms try to maximize profits and that CSR can be viewed as an investment. However, we do not model CSR as a differentiation strategy but consider its effect on transaction costs, emissions and risk. As in McWilliams and Siegel (2001), we assume that firms must devote resources for CSR activities. We, hence, consider the tradeoff between the costs to generate CSR attributes and the benefits, which include lower risk, lower emissions and lower costs in the long run. We explicitly include the behavior of decision-makers within the supply chain as well as the supply chain structure while we implicitly include institutional factors in the cost and risk functions. The model is flexible enough to analyze how different objectives of firms (McWilliams and Siegel, 2001), legal and institutional factors (Williams and Aguilera, 2008), and country differences (Matten and Moon, 2008) impact optimal CSR levels. Cruz (2008) considered CSR activities and risk management in a single period setting in addition to the concept of environmental decision-making. In this paper, however, we turn to the critical issue of social responsibility activities and risk management in a multiperiod supply chain network framework. As the previous section highlighted, CSR activities lead to many long-term effects that are essential in the cost–benefit analysis of CSR activities. These long-term effects were not considered in Cruz (2008). The multiperiod framework allows us to explicitly capture these long-term effects and, hence, provides a valuable extension of previous research. Furthermore, it allows us to see how changes in the planning framework impact the decision-making, the resulting payoffs and costs. This paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we develop the multitiered, multiperiod supply chain network model. We describe decision-makers’ optimizing behavior and establish the governing equilibrium conditions along with the corresponding variational inequality formulation. In Section 3, we propose an algorithm and present computational studies. In Section 4, we discuss the results. We conclude the paper with Section 5 in which we summarize our results and suggest directions for future research.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

CSR can potentially decrease production inefficiencies, reduce cost and risk and at the same time allow companies to increase sales. As a result of lower costs, lower risk and increase in sales, companies become more profitable. However, we expect that as the investment in CSR activities increases, the return on investment is decreasing. Therefore, it is very important for managers to find the optimal level of investment in CSR activities so that he n she can allocate the appropriate amount of resources to these activities over time. The optimal levels of CSR activities are impacted by factors within the firm as well as its business environment. In this paper, we develop a framework for the analysis of the optimal levels of CSR activities in a multiperiod supply chain network consisting of manufacturers, retai- lers, and consumers. The framework explicitly includes the behavior of decision-makers within the supply chain as well as the supply chain structure while it implicitly includes institutional factors in the cost and risk func- tions. Manufacturers and retailers are multicriteria deci- sion-makers who decide about their production and transaction quantities as well as the amount of social responsibility activities they want to pursue to maximize net return, minimize emissions, and minimize risk over the multiperiod planning horizon. We construct the finite- dimensional variational inequality governing the equili- brium of the multiperiod competitive supply chain net- work. The model allows us to investigate the interplay of the heterogeneous decision-makers in the supply chain network and to compute the resultant equilibrium pattern of product outputs, transactions, product prices, and levels of social responsibility activities. A computational proce- dure that exploits the network structure of the problem is proposed and then applied to several numerical examples. We analyze the impact of the cost of CSR on the investment level in CSR activities. We found that as the cost of CSR activities increases the firm will have less incentive to invest in them. Here, as in McWilliams and Siegel (2001) , the ideal level of CSR should be determined by a long-term cost benefit analysis. In the short run, the cost of CSR may seem high, however, this cost would be less in the long run compared to the cost of liability for pollution, compliance with regulation, dangerous opera- tions, use of hazardous raw materials, production of hazardous waste, and health and safety issues. Moreover, these liabilities may cost companies their reputation ( Dowling, 2001; Fombrun, 2001 ), brand image, sales, access to markets and financial investments ( Feldman et al., 1997 ). In conclusion, managers should treat their decision regarding CSR as they treat all their long-term investment decisions. The numerical examples highlight that the best out- come for the supply chain as a whole might not always be achieved if each member in the supply chain determines the optimal levels of CSR only based on his/her own costs and benefits. It is important that CSR activities are coordinated among different firms in the supply chain. Increased coordination among firms in the supply chain leads to a multitude of additional positive effects. It has the potential to reduce network-related risk ( Johnson, 2001; Norrman and Jansson, 2004 ). Furthermore, Simpson and Power (2005) indicate that strong relationships in the network are capable of leading to programs of collabora- tive waste reduction, environmental innovation at the interface, cost-effective environmental solutions, the rapid development and uptake of innovation in environ- mental technologies, and allows firms to better under- stand the environmental impact of their supply chains. The model is flexible enough to analyze how different objectives of firms ( McWilliams and Siegel, 2001 ), legal and institutional factors ( Williams and Aguilera, 2008 ), and country differences ( Matten and Moon, 2008 ) impact optimal CSR levels. The model developed in this paper provides a foundation for future studies that attempt to test assumptions in the conceptual literature. As a first step it is necessary to empirically validate the following relationships: (1) the relationship between levels of social responsibility activities and transaction costs; (2) the relationship between levels of social responsibility activities and total emission (waste) generated; and (3) the CSR n risk n profit relationships. Second, as operations of the firms become more globalized it is important to analyze how the concept of CSR is applied in different countries with different culture, as well as rules and regulation. Future research will also include the extension of this framework to the international arena. Finally, we shall develop a dynamic model that takes into consideration the rate of change in price, cost, risk, and profit as the investment in CSR increases or decreases over time.