دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 23582
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

تاثیر اثرات فضایی در درآمد نیروی باد تحت قوانین بازاریابی مستقیم

عنوان انگلیسی
The influence of spatial effects on wind power revenues under direct marketing rules
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
23582 2013 11 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Energy Policy, Volume 58, July 2013, Pages 237–247

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
- قدرت باد - مدل حق بیمه بازار - زمینه های بهینه تولید
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Wind power,Market premium model,Optimal areas of production
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  تاثیر اثرات فضایی در درآمد نیروی باد تحت قوانین بازاریابی مستقیم

چکیده انگلیسی

In many countries, investments in renewable technologies have been accelerated by fixed feed-in tariffs for electricity from renewable energy sources (RES). While fixed tariffs accomplish this purpose, they lack incentives to align the RES production with price signals. Today, the intermittency of most RES increases the volatility of electricity prices and makes balancing supply and demand more complicated. Therefore, support schemes for RES have to be modified. Recently, Germany launched a scheme which gives wind power operators the monthly choice to either receive a fixed tariff or to risk a – subsidized – access to the wholesale electricity market. This paper quantifies revenues of wind turbines under this new subsidy and analyzes whether, when and where producers may profit. We find that the position of the wind turbine within the country significantly influences revenues in terms of EUR/MWh. The results are important for wind farm operators deciding whether electricity should be sold in the fixed feed-in tariff or in the wholesale market. However, no location is persistently, i.e., in every calendar month of the year, above the average. This limits the effect of the new subsidy scheme on investment locations and long term improvements in the aggregated wind feed-in profile.

مقدمه انگلیسی

The promotion of electricity generation from renewable energy sources (RES) is a key element of the European energy policy. As of today, without additional subsidies electricity generation from RES cannot economically compete with generation from other sources (especially thermal power plants). Hence, politicians in many European countries, including Germany, decided to subsidize RES-generation with feed-in tariffs. In this paper, we focus on the subsidization scheme of Germany and on German wind power generation. Wind power is one of the largest and most promising sources of renewable energy within the country. In Germany, feed-in tariffs are specified in the Renewable Energy Sources Act (RESA). These feed-in tariffs are the main incentive to build renewable energy plants as they guarantee a revenue for every unit of energy produced by renewable technologies. The act was established in 2000 and successfully increased the share of energy generation from wind and other RES in Germany. For example, at the end of 2011 a total of about 22 000 wind turbines was installed. Electricity generation from all RES amounted to 20% of the total electricity consumption in Germany in the first half of 2011. However, increasing shares of RES led to new challenges, especially in terms of integrating RES-generation in the conventional wholesale electricity market. In a system with fixed feed-in tariffs, RES operators have no incentive to reduce output, although, e.g., wind plants are often able to do this at low costs. If an increasing share of supply – in addition to large parts of demand – is price inelastic, the remaining part of the market (i.e., mostly thermal generation capacity) has to balance supply and demand. Hence, price volatility increases. Without additional flexibility, the market may not even clear during certain hours as the inelastic available production from wind and other price inelastic sources may exceed desired demand. Furthermore, problems might also arise in the opposite case when price inelastic generation from RES and remaining thermal capacity is too low to cover demand. Various possible solutions for these challenges are currently being discussed. One approach is an improved demand-side management (i.e., increasing the price elasticity of demand). In addition, available storage capacity could be increased. Furthermore, grid extensions could increase the market, thus allowing for more balanced supply and demand profiles. Another interesting idea, from an economic perspective, is to bring RES closer to the wholesale market, with the aim of increasing the price elasticity of supply. These challenges will become even more important in the future, when RES shares increase further. The current political goals for future shares of RES in the total electricity production are 35% in 2020, 50% in 2030 and 80% in 2050.1 Consequently, the German parliament passed a new version of the Renewable Energy Sources Act (in the following called RESA2012) which addresses these aspects. The act became effective January 1st, 2012. One key aspect of RESA2012 is an improved direct marketing approach as an alternative to the feed-in tariff. The goal is to set incentives to sell electricity generation from RES directly in the wholesale electricity market in order to link the produced energy to price signals. The general idea of RESA2012 is that electricity generation from RES receives the wholesale electricity price. As this will not cover RES total costs (and is below current earnings in the feed-in tariff), an additional subsidy is paid to compensate for the difference between feed-in tariff and wholesale market prices. This subsidy is called ’market premium’. The market premium a wind turbine receives is calculated retrospectively for each month and depends on the hourly feed-in profile of the particular station in the particular month and on the profiles of all other stations as a reference. The short-run effect on the dispatch of wind is probably limited due to generation costs close to zero. However, some effect can be expected for the case when generation from renewables exceeds demand because the incentive to reduce generation from wind power is higher in the market premium system than it is for fixed feed-in tariffs. Additional positive aspects are possible in the long run in the market premium system as a location's payoff profile will be included in the investment decision in addition to the total energy output. More detailed discussions of the general efficiency or the compatibility of the incentives set for investing in renewable energy may be found in a variety of papers, e.g., the recent papers of Faúndez (2008), Mulder (2008), Marques et al. (2011), Cansino et al. (2010), Desrochers (2008) and Lipp (2007). A historical overview of incentive schemes for renewable energy in Europe is given in, e.g., Haas et al. (2011). In this paper, we take the subsidy scheme in RESA2012 as given and focus on the quantification of the effects it will have on wind turbines. We analyze onshore wind turbines only, since the proportion of offshore wind parks is still very small and there is no historical data regarding offshore installations. In particular, we analyze the effect which the location of a wind turbine has on its revenue. As direct marketing in RESA2012 subsidizes a turbine's energy in €/MWh€/MWh based on the nationwide wind feed-in profile, the relation of the turbine's power profile to the nationwide wind feed-in profile is a significant additional revenue component under the new scheme. If a turbine tends to produce energy in times where the nationwide wind energy production is relatively low, i.e., if its power production is anticorrelated to the total wind power production, revenues will be higher than for a production profile which is in line with the nationwide production. Electricity prices and wind generation are negatively correlated in systems with a high wind penetration because a high wind generation replaces thermal capacity thus setting the price at a lower level. In times of low wind generation, prices are high but wind profits under proportionally. The production profile of a wind turbine is determined by the wind speeds at its geographical position. Therefore, the position of a wind turbine is decisive for the revenue potential of wind energy in RESA2012. In the short term, information on this revenue potential is valuable for the operators of 22 000 wind turbines currently installed in Germany. In the long run, it can be used as an input to quantify the incentive to build future wind turbines in locations with more valuable pay-off profiles and thus increase efficiency in the system. To our knowledge, no other publication has analyzed this effect so far. It has been studied for some time, however, that dependencies (e.g., correlations) of wind speeds at distant locations affect the accumulated wind power production of wind turbines. Kahn (1979) systematically analyzed these effects for arrays of Californian wind farms of different sizes. In a recent study based on copula functions, Grothe and Schnieders (2011) analyzed dependencies of wind power positions in Germany. In this study, we go a step further and analyze the effect of the position (and the unit specific production profile) on a wind turbine's revenue under the subsidized direct marketing of RESA2012. In a first step, we use hourly wind speed data from different locations to calculate the hourly electricity production that a reference wind turbine would have produced in a particular place. Then, we calculate the relative performance for a representative unit at each location based on these electricity production estimates, the nationwide historical total feed-in of all wind turbines, and hourly electricity prices for the 12 months period from July 2010 to June 2011. However, as we are interested in making recommendations for the future, the question remains whether a good performance during the analyzed year was achieved by chance or was rather the result of a statistically significant negative dependence of the unit's feed-in with nationwide feed-in. Hence, in a second step, we analyze an extended period of observation from 2001 to 2011. Since no consistent dataset for nationwide feed-in exists (the four German TSOs started reporting nationwide data on 2009-10-29), we use our set of hourly wind data for the different locations to estimate the nationwide feed-in for the extended period of observation. Then, again using electricity production estimates for the different locations, the estimated nationwide feed-in and historic hourly wholesale electricity prices, we calculate the relative performance for all locations in the extended time period. We are thus able to estimate at which location (and in which season and month) the new scheme leads to systematically higher or lower revenues when compared to the fixed feed-in tariff. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: In Section 2 we review the German Renewable Energy Sources Act with special focus on wind energy. In Section 3 we introduce the methodology and data used in the paper. Descriptive tables regarding the data are listed in the appendix. Our empirical analysis is presented in Section 4. Section 5 concludes.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

This paper analyzes the effect of the location of a wind turbine on its revenue under the new direct marketing approach introduced by Germany's Renewable Energy Sources Act 2012. Based on RESA2012, wind turbine operators have the free and monthly choice to either sell their electricity generation according to the new direct marketing approach or to receive a fixed feed-in tariff. We find that the position of a turbine within the country affects its expected revenues by up to 5–6 EUR per produced MWh in the direct marketing approach. However, this effect varies from month to month. For example, turbines at certain locations may receive above-average revenues per MWh in the summer months, whereas their revenues per MWh in winter months may be below average. Our study calculates monthly revenues for 37 German regions based on hourly wind data from the last 10 years. The results can aid the operators of 22 000 wind turbines in Germany in the decision which subsidy is more profitable for a given plant in a given month. Our results could also be used for risk management purposes, i.e., to quantify the risk associated with the decision for the direct market access compared to a fixed feed-in tariff. Furthermore, together with information on the total amount of electricity expected at a certain location the results can be used to guide new investments to more profitable locations. This would at the same time increase efficiency in the system because the overall production of wind energy would then be more aligned with scarcity signals, i.e., prices. However, since the monthly effect is not constant over the year, the effect on guiding investments to locations with generation profiles that are more in line with demand are probably limited. Furthermore, existing price differences between locations will decrease with additional investments as higher generation at profitable locations will lower prices. In the current paper, we abstracted from this effect. A quantification of the net effect of added capacities is, however, an interesting question. A current study for Germany (Ketterer, 2012) finds a decrease of electricity prices by about 0.1% when the wind electricity feed-in increases by 1%. The older German study of Neubarth et al. (2006) estimates that 1000 MW additional wind generation in an hour lower electricity prices by View the MathML source1.90€/MWh. Based on the latter study a very rough estimate would be that an advantage of 6 EUR at a location vanishes when about 3000 MW are additionally produced at this location. This is a significant amount for any specific location. In this sense our results are relatively robust against changes in wind capacity. However, the mentioned studies look at average numbers and do not take the actual wind profiles into account which is crucial to calculate the numbers in our paper. Therefore a correct calculation requires detailed analyzes considering not only the average impact of wind energy on prices but also spatial effects within this impact. Hence, we see potential for further research in this area. Furthermore, we do not take into account future changes in the energy mix. The future energy mix is unknown and depends for example on the political environment in Germany during the next decades. Nonetheless, the proportion of RES in the energy mix will most likely continue to grow. For larger proportions of wind energy, our results can be seen as lower bounds of the effect because the effect of wind power on wholesale prices will be even higher and the effect of a good location is at least as large as in our computations. Nevertheless, it remains an important task to model the changes in the energy mix and we encourage researchers to do so. To improve the empirical value of our results, our methodology can be applied to unit specific wind data as well. Given our estimate of total nationwide historical feed-in, further analyzes do not necessitate a new representative set of data. Instead, individual units (or wind farm locations) could be analyzed.