Trade data are often classified by product characteristics. We propose a new classification “sophistication” as a means of distinguishing between products. We construct a sophistication index based on the income levels of exporting economies. Sophistication captures a range of factors including technology, ease of product fragmentation, natural resource availability, and marketing. We calculate sophistication scores at the 3- and 4-digit levels and test how far the index relates to existing technological classifications of products. We use the index to examine trade patterns and illustrate how it can be applied in the analysis of export performance of individual economies.
Researchers seeking to explain trade flows or to assess the competitiveness of individual economies have long sought ways of classifying and categorizing the vast and ever increasing range of products that enter into world trade. Classification by factor intensity and technological intensity are two popular ways of addressing this issue that has yielded useful insights. A basic problem with both approaches however stems from the relatively high level of aggregation at which both can be applied. Factor input data will normally come from input–output tables or industrial censuses, typically at a 2-digit level, while technology classifications are normally based on R&D expenditure by the manufacturing sub-sector. Trade data, on the other hand, are available at highly disaggregated levels: for instance, the Standard International Trade Classification (SITC) Revision 2 has 236 items at the 3-digit level and 778 items at the 4-digit level. In the 2002 version of the Harmonized System, the new trade data recording system, there are over 1 200 items at the 4-digit level and over 5 000 items at the 6-digit level. In contrast, in relation to R&D expenditure, US data are available for only 38 manufacturing industries (NSB, 2002), while the OECD Science, Technology, and Industry Scoreboard provides cross-country R&D data for 19 industries.
Given the extensive and disaggregate information on products that enter international trade, it is useful to have a means of distinguishing between similar products produced by different countries and to have a broad indication of product differences at a highly disaggregate level. With this aim we put forward a new method of classifying exports that does not require industry data, but only information on exports of each product and per capita incomes of exporting countries. We term this a “sophistication index” and calculate sophistication scores for 1990 and 2000 for 237 products at the 3-digit level (of SITC Revision 2), and for 766 products at the 4-digit level.1 We show how the index can be used in comparisons of export structure and in discussions of individual country competitiveness.
Section 2 explains the calculation of our index. Section 3 discusses individual product scores at the 3- and 4-digit levels and relates the index to one well-known set of technology categories. Section 4 discusses the results when product data are aggregated for individual countries and the potential use of the index in discussions of export promotion and competitiveness strategies. Finally, we draw some conclusions.
‘Sophistication’’ provides a new way of ana-
lyzing trade and location patterns and tracking
export composition and competitiveness in
developing countries. Its main advantage is that
it can be calculated quickly at any level of detail
and for any period. It can provide unique
scores for products at disaggregated levels. Its
main disadvantage is that it is not a specific
technology measure: it captures many other
factors affecting export location, and care is
needed in interpreting the results.
—Sophistication correlates relatively poorly
with technology and in particular its impact
is diluted by fragmentation, which allows
technology-intensive activities to locate
exports in countries that received theory
would not predict. However, all ‘‘fragment-
able’’ activities (with discrete processes) do
not fragment to similar extents: sophistica-
tion provides a useful tool to map this and
identify activities with ‘‘location inertia.’’
This can lead to further research on the
causes of inertia—economies of agglomera-
tion, links with innovation systems, special
skill needs, government policy, and soon—and provide insights to countries that
wish to attract or upgrade those industries.
—Resource-based exports have the obvious
pattern that has little to do with income
levels (that is countries export products for
which they have the resources). However,
there are exceptions caused by technological
factors (accumulated skills), marketing and
brands, and government protection and sub-
sidization.
—In the aggregate sophistication does not
have a strong relationship with growth rates.
Exports by richer countries do not grow rel-
atively fast: industrial catch-up means that
exports by poorer countries are likely to
grow more rapidly, aided by relocation of
activities within global value chains. Thus,
there is widespread (but not universal)
‘‘de-sophistication’’ of manufactured prod-
ucts.
—Exports at the bottom of the sophistication
scale largely from poor countries do not grow
rapidly. Most products in this category have
a low income elasticity of demand and may
be suffering from declining prices. The poor-
est countries lack the industrial capabilities
to move into more attractive products or
attract hi-tech production networks. Low
wages
per se
are not the driver of relocation
but low wages for technically proficient
workers, backed by modern infrastructure,
suppliers, and other capability and institu-
tional factors needed for modern industry.
Bythesamereasoning,havinghighpercapita
incomes is not a guarantee of a sophisticated
export structure. Countries may become rich
without building advanced industrial skills
and capabilities; doing this requires specific
strategies. This is clearly illustrated by the
contrast between the low sophistication
export structure of Hong Kong, China, one
of the richest countries in East Asia, and the
more advanced export structures of other
mature Tigers in the region.
—The ‘‘de-sophistication’’ process is thus
highly skewed. It is largely a shift from
high- to middle-income countries, not to
the poorest ones (a differently constructed
sophistication index could illustrate this).
There is a bulge in the middle of the global
sophistication scale, where the largest and
most dynamic exports are concentrated.
—Aggregate sophistication scores by coun-
try conform broadly to expectations, with
South Asian economies near the bottom of
the scale.While this paper is only a first cut at using the
sophistication index, it suggests that the tech-
nique can be useful in several ways. First, the
scores are product specific and can be as de-
tailed as needed. This allows the index to be
applied as a continuous variable for econo-
metric analysis. Second, in conjunction with
technology and value chain information,
sophistication data can be used to analyze
fragmentation and location inertia. Third, our
sophistication index can be used as a prelimin-
ary step for country competitiveness analysis,
allowing a rapid mapping of location shifts inexports of interest to a country. More broadly,
it can show if a country’s sophistication struc-
ture of its exports is in line with its income level.
Although the normative implications of this
data are limited, they provide a starting point
for more detailed analysis.
We argue that the index provides a useful,
new way of organizing very detailed trade data.
More work is needed to refine the index and
construct other indices (geared to middle and
low income countries or to finer levels of prod-
uct detail). It is hoped that this preliminary
exploration will stimulate such work