دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 16200
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

رقابت ناقص در تطبیق دو طرفه بازار

عنوان انگلیسی
Imperfect competition in two-sided matching markets
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
16200 2014 17 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Games and Economic Behavior, Volume 83, January 2014, Pages 207–223

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
جستجوی بازار - رقابت ناقص - تطبیق دو طرفه بازار -
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Matching markets, Imperfect competition,two-sided matching markets ,
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  رقابت ناقص در تطبیق دو طرفه بازار

چکیده انگلیسی

This paper considers a simple equilibrium model of an imperfectly competitive two-sided matching market. Firms and workers may have heterogeneous preferences over matches on the other side, and the model allows for both uniform and personalized wages or contracts. To make the model tractable, I use the Azevedo and Leshno (2013) framework, in which a finite number of firms is matched to a continuum of workers. In equilibrium, even if wages are exogenous and fixed, firms have incentives to strategically reduce their capacity, to increase the quality of their worker pool. The intensity of incentives to reduce capacity is given by a simple formula, analogous to the classic Cournot model, but depends on different moments of the distribution of preferences. I compare markets with uniform and personalized wages. For fixed quantities, markets with personalized wages always yield higher efficiency than markets with uniform wages, but may be less efficient if firms reduce capacity to avoid bidding too much for star workers.

مقدمه انگلیسی

Two-sided matching markets are markets where participants on either side have preferences over who they interact with on the other side. Examples include matching CEOs to companies, students to colleges, advertisers to content providers, and many entry-level labor markets.1 A stable matching is an allocation in which agents do not have incentives to break away from their matches and seek new ones. A well-known result by Roth (1985) shows that no mechanism that always produces a stable matching is strategy-proof for the firms. However, even though these markets have been studied by a large literature, most contributions ignore strategic behavior by firms, assuming them to command insignificant market share, or to act naïvely. This is in contrast to the standard approach in industrial organization, which typically focuses on Nash equilibrium in imperfectly competitive markets. This paper considers how the standard questions in imperfect competition models play out in matching markets. First, I investigate strategic quantity choices by firms, such as colleges or hospitals in centralized clearinghouses. Second, I consider the consequences of strategic behavior to equilibrium outcomes, and third, discuss a modest set of implications for the regulation and design of matching markets. I consider a model analogous to Cournot oligopoly, but in a matching market. In the model, a number of firms compete to be matched to a set of workers. Both workers and firms have potentially heterogeneous preferences over match partners on the other side. I follow the literature on capacity manipulation games (Konishi and Ünver, 2006, Kojima, 2006, Mumcu and Saglam, 2009 and Ehlers, 2010), assuming that firms strategically set capacity. Workers are then assigned according to a stable matching. This is analogous to the Cournot model, in which firms choose capacities, and prices are given by market clearing. The model departs from the literature in two key ways. First, instead of the standard Becker (1973) or Gale and Shapley (1962) frameworks, I use the Azevedo and Leshno (2013) model, in which a finite number of firms is matched to a continuum of workers.2 The continuum model considerably simplifies the analysis, and reveals novel insights akin to standard price-theoretic analyses. Second, I consider the cases of both uniform and of personalized wages. I first consider the case in which wages are exogenous, and uniform across workers. A surprising result from the matching literature on capacity manipulation is that firms may want to reduce quantities even if wages are fixed (Sönmez, 1997 and Kesten, 2008). The intuition is that, by reducing capacity, firms may create rejection chains, in which a rejected worker causes further rejections, and eventually causes a better worker to apply to the firm. This can increase the quality of the worker pool available to the firm, at the expense of reducing the quantity of workers hired. Unsurprisingly, this result is still true in my model. However, unlike the previous literature, with the Azevedo and Leshno (2013) model, there is a simple first-order condition that quantifies the incentives to reduce capacity. The model shows that, if a firm is negligible compared to the rest of the market, it has no incentives to reduce capacity. However, if a firm has some market power, its marginal revenue from increasing capacity is lower than the productivity of a marginal worker. The reason for this is that, when a large firm hires more workers, it poaches employees from the competition, which leads competitors to be less selective. The first-order conditions show that the wedge in marginal revenue is proportional to the effect of a firm on the selectiveness of its competitors. This result clarifies the link between the matching literature on capacity manipulation games and the Cournot model. Although the basic logic of the Cournot model extends to matching markets, some of the results have to be modified. For example, in the undifferentiated Cournot model the incentives for each firm to reduce capacity, as measured by the Lerner index, only depend on the inverse elasticity of demand and market share. This is not true in matching markets, where the incentives to shade depend on very different moments of the distribution of preferences. Therefore, the present model has a wealth of predictions that differ from the standard findings in homogeneous good markets. In particular, we highlight that, while the model assumptions are analogous to Cournot, the results often are not. Therefore, it is not appropriate to view every implication of the present model as analogous to implications of the standard Cournot model. After considering uniform fixed wages, the paper considers matching markets with personalized wages. To my knowledge, this type of analysis has not been pursued in the literature for markets in which agents have heterogeneous preferences. It is shown that firms still have an incentive to reduce capacity, and a simple first-order condition quantifies by how much. Interestingly, the reasons for reducing capacity are quite different when wages are personalized. The gain is no longer caused by rejection chains, but by the fact that rejecting workers leads other firms to bid less aggressively for the best workers. The paper then compares markets that have personalized wages and markets that have uniform wages. For example, in the market for junior associates in elite New York law firms, most firms pay every incoming lawyer the same wage. In contrast, senior lawyers are often paid personalized wages (Ginsburg and Wolf, 2003). A series of papers have debated the desirability of using personalized wages, which is a key market design variable. Notably, Bulow and Levin (2006) have shown that uniform wages may reduce matching efficiency, and compress wages. I show, however, that if firms choose capacities this conclusion may be reversed. In the imperfect competition model, there is a tradeoff. Personalized wages always generate higher matching efficiency for a given level of capacity, but they may increase firmsʼ incentives to shade capacity. If firms are very similar, personalized wages have little impact on matching efficiency, but may induce firms to drastically reduce capacity to avoid entering into a bidding war for the best employees. In that case, markets organized around uniform wages generate higher welfare. However, if firms are more heterogeneous, the loss from matching inefficiency dominates the loss from capacity reduction, and personalized wages generate higher efficiency. The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 discusses the basic model, in which workers are paid uniform, fixed wages. Section 3 introduces personalized wages. Section 4 compares these two different institutional settings, and Section 5 concludes. Omitted proofs are in Appendix A.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

This paper considers an equilibrium model of imperfect competition in many-to-one matching markets. This is a first step towards understanding firm behavior, and its implications for the design and regulation of matching markets. The main contribution is to extend standard price-theoretic insights of the Cournot model to matching markets, and understand to what extent these insights have to be modified. Market power induces a wedge between the marginal revenue of a firm, and the net productivity of a marginal hired worker. Interestingly, the determinants of the size of this wedge are very different when wages are uniform or personalized. With uniform wages, the wedge exists due to heterogeneous preferences between firms, which means that rejecting a worker may create a beneficial rejection chain. In contrast, when wages are personalized, the wedge exists because of aligned preferences. Firms that reduce capacity increase the pool of available workers, which induces competitors to bid less aggressively for workers that both firms covet. As an application, these insights contribute to the debate over the desirability of uniform versus flexible wages. We have seen that taking strategic capacity setting into account qualifies the Bulow and Levin (2006) conclusion that flexible wages always generate more efficiency. In the Bulow and Levin model, if firms are allowed to choose capacity, flexible wages do produce higher matching efficiency given quantities, but they also give more incentives for firms to reduce capacities. Flexible wages are still more efficient if firms are sufficiently heterogeneous. However, if firms are very similar, so that the loss from matching inefficiency is small, uniform wages produce higher welfare, as they induce less capacity reduction. We note that, although this conclusion is intuitive, it relies on our assumption of quantity competition. It would be interesting to investigate to which extent it holds under other types of firm competition. An important limitation of the analysis is that we only consider quantity competition. While in industrial organization quantity competition models figure prominently, they are by no means the only models available. As such, the assumption of quantity competition should be seen as a first step towards understanding strategic behavior in matching markets. It would be interesting to explore matching markets in which firms have a different set of strategic variables at their disposal. For example, models where firms can differentiate themselves, tailor products to specific market segments, or misrepresent their preferences. An interesting application of analyzing behavior under different strategic variables is to compare different market design choices for centralized clearinghouses. For example, in the model of quantity competition we have shown that firms have incentives to reduce capacity. It can be shown that, if firms were to choose cutoffs, and quantities were assigned by market clearing, then in equilibrium firms would not have incentives to shade. This suggests that, in a market with perfect information and no aggregate randomness, in which firms cannot misreport their preference rankings, a clearinghouse in which firms choose cutoffs would perform better than one in which they report capacities. Naturally, this conclusion is subject to the caveat that, if there is some aggregate randomness in the market, having firms report cutoffs subjects them to the risk of getting too many or too few workers. Therefore, the comparison between these two rules will depend on the cost of firms matching to a number of workers that is different than ideal, on the level of aggregate randomness, and on whether firms can misrepresent preference orderings. Nevertheless, comparing different matching mechanisms by their equilibrium properties is an interesting direction for research, and is complementary to the axiomatic approach that most of the literature takes.