دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 17802
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

اثربخشی محدودیت های موقعیت : شواهدی از بازار آتی ارز

عنوان انگلیسی
The effectiveness of position limits : Evidence from the foreign exchange futures markets
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
17802 2013 9 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Journal of Banking & Finance, Volume 37, Issue 11, November 2013, Pages 4501–4509

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
کیفیت خدمات - سهام اطلاعات - کشف قیمت - محدودیت های موقعیت - حدس و گمان -
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Hedging, Information shares, Price discovery, Position limits, Speculation,
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  اثربخشی محدودیت های موقعیت : شواهدی از بازار آتی ارز

چکیده انگلیسی

This study considers the effects of the relative size of hedger and speculator open interests and the potential impact of implementing position limits on the price discovery process in both JPY–USD and EUR–USD futures markets. Hedging trading exerts a negative impact, regardless of its size, on price discovery in futures markets. Hedgers are less likely to be information motivated, so their trading uniformly delays the price discovery process. However, there is a positive and nonlinear impact of speculators’ trade size on price discovery, the contribution of which depends on the relative size of the speculative open interest. Contrary to conventional wisdom among regulators, speculative trading does not harm the market in terms of market efficiency; as long as the percentage of speculators’ open interest is below an endogenously determined threshold (approximately 20% for EUR–USD and 16.3% for JPY–USD), speculative trading even improves futures market efficiency.

مقدمه انگلیسی

During a 2009 hearing of the Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC) regarding the use of position limits to control excessive speculation in the commodity futures markets, CFTC Chair Gary Gensler asserted, “No longer must we debate the issue of whether or not to set position limits… it’s more a question of how than whether” (Acworth, 2009). He further explained that the CFTC was required by statute to apply position limits to prevent “undue burdens” caused by excessive speculation. This explanation reflects the strong beliefs among regulators that limiting speculative positions is beneficial, such that the Commodity Exchange Act even applies speculative position limits or position accountability for speculators in some futures markets. Yet little empirical evidence confirms whether efficient futures markets pricing actually improved with the imposition of speculative position limits, how the sizes of position limits should be set, and whether exemptions of position size should be granted to hedgers. In particular, the effectiveness of derivative market position limits remains subject to debate. Kyle (1984) and Kumar and Seppi (1992) argue that position limits are important for controlling market manipulations. Position limits in futures markets have been applied widely in practice, in efforts to contain speculators’ participation and stabilize futures prices. However, Gastineau, 1992 and Telser, 1993, and Grossman (1993) posit that position limits are ineffective controls for market manipulation, and Gastineau and Jarrow (1991) argue that arbitrary position limits even reduce market liquidity and induce nonsynchronous pricing in related markets. According to Grossman (1993), with position limits, speculators shift to foreign or substitute markets. Dutt and Harris (2005) document controversies about the use of position limits. Furthermore, to the best of our knowledge, theoretical and empirical evidence regarding the effect of hedging trading on market efficiency is virtually nonexistent. Overall then, empirical evidence of the effectiveness of either hedging or speculative position limits remains scarce. We therefore examine the impact of the position sizes of hedgers and speculators on the price discovery process and explore the potential impact of implementing position limits in the JPY–USD and EUR–USD futures markets. Increasing understanding of the impact of hedgers and speculators on price discovery is important for both academia and regulators, because relative trading positions have implications for the effectiveness of position limits, as well as for market quality. Most commodity futures and many financial futures markets have stipulated (likely arbitrary) speculative position limits, set by the CFTC or the exchanges themselves. In our sample, the currency futures are not subject to position limits.1 Thus, we apply nonlinear regressions to find endogenous change points for the position sizes, which then serve as a guide to assist in the determination of position limits. We examine their hypothetical effectiveness, were such limits to be set. Accordingly, we summarize the position accountability and/or position limit requirements of the Chicago Mercantile Exchange (CME) currency futures contracts, as we show in the Appendix A. Substantial literature has emerged to investigate lead–lag relationships and contributions to price discovery between the foreign exchange (FX) spot and futures markets.2 Studying price discovery allows us to determine how markets incorporate new information about the underlying fundamental asset value. In this paper, we consider how positions of various types of traders affect the price discovery function of the futures market relative to the spot market. To capture the nonlinearity in the dynamic process of price discovery of futures/spot markets, we estimate a nonlinear, logistic smooth transition regression (LSTR) model to trace the dependence between information efficiency and the relative positions of hedgers and speculators in the FX futures market, using data of hedgers’ and speculators’ positions collected from the weekly commitment of traders (COT) report from the CFTC.3 The impact of trading activities on futures market efficiency may vary with the relative magnitude of hedgers’ and speculators’ trading. Gastineau and Jarrow (1991) note that when speculative trading is not dominant, it may contribute positively to market efficiency, because it can help impound private information into prices. In contrast, if speculators’ transactions constitute a large proportion of total market activity, their trading may destabilize prices.4 This situation implies a potential nonlinear effect of relative hedging versus speculative trading on the futures market’s share in the discovery of efficient prices. Therefore, our study of nonlinear dynamics in price discovery and finding an endogenously determined threshold level of trading positions that affect the interaction between price discovery and trading position is valuable for regulators who must establish position limits and trading rules. According to Keynes, 1930 and Keynes, 1983 normal backwardation theory, hedgers have net short positions in futures markets, so they can transfer their exposure risk in the spot market. Their hedging pressure tends to drive down futures prices relative to the expected value of the spot price, resulting in mispricing in futures markets. Several studies, including those by Houthakker (1957) and Cootner (1960), have reformulated original backwardation theory to allow hedgers’ positions to be net long, such that futures prices may be higher than the expected future spot prices.5 However, speculators who enter on the opposite side of the futures contracts bear risks and receive compensation in the form of a positive expected profit on their positions. The presence of speculators causes futures prices to be revised toward the expected value of spot prices. According to these arguments, hedgers’ trading activity should lead to mispricing; speculators’ activity should provide liquidity and pricing corrections. In turn, the speculators’ (hedgers’) trading activities seemingly have a more positive (negative) impact on market efficiency. However, several studies indicate exactly opposite informational roles played by speculators and hedgers. Wang (2002a) finds that hedgers in currency futures are typically large commercial banks, multinational corporations, or commercial dealers with private information, because they have more customer order flows from spot and forwards markets. In addition, they may have their own seats in futures exchanges, so they can benefit from gathering information. Wang (2002a) argues that speculators and small traders in the currency futures markets are likely uninformed.6 These uninformed traders may trade irrationally in response to noise and overreact to information. According to these arguments, speculators’ (hedgers’) trading activities provide a negative (positive) contribution to price discovery, in direct contrast with the theory of normal backwardation. The exact information roles that hedgers and speculators play thus remain empirical questions and may depend on their relative position sizes. We use a two-stage procedure to examine the impact of the trading positions held by hedgers and speculators on price discovery in FX futures traded on the CME. To begin, we use the information share approach of Hasbrouck (1995) to evaluate the weekly contributions of JPY–USD and EUR–USD futures markets to the futures/ spot price discovery process. With measures of information shares for the futures market, we can estimate the logistic smooth transition regression (LSTR) model to determine how the efficacy of price discovery depends on the trading positions held by hedgers and speculators in the JPY–USD and EUR–USD futures markets. Our results indicate that the relative trading activities of hedgers (speculators) relate negatively (positively) to the price discovery function of the JPY–USD and EUR–USD futures markets, in support of the normal backwardation and hedging pressure hypotheses.7 That is, the presence of more hedgers in the market induces prices to move away from the efficient price. Instead, speculators’ trading improves the futures market’s efficacy in responding to price-relevant information, implying the degree of mispricing in the futures market declines with speculators’ trading. This finding highlights the positive contributions of speculative trading to futures market efficiency, even though regulators around the world are wary of such activities. Furthermore, we provide evidence of a nonlinear relationship between speculators’ trading and price discovery. The significance of speculators’ positive contributions to price discovery depends on their position size, relative to that of hedgers. In particular, speculative trading improves the degree of price discovery in the EUR–USD (JPY–USD) futures market when the proportion of speculative trading volume is less than 20% (16.3%); when the proportion of speculative trading exceeds 20% (16.3%), its impact on the futures market’s efficiency in incorporating information into prices becomes neutral. Yet speculative trading always makes at least non-negative contributions to the price discovery process. Finally, we find that the relationship between volatility and price discovery in the futures market depends on the relative proportion of speculative trading: The futures market’s information share increases (decreases) with volatility when speculative trading is relatively low (high). When speculative trading is not dominant, the greater volatility can be attributed to the incorporation of newly arriving information into market prices. In contrast, with excessive speculative trading, noisy trading dominates informative trading, and extremely high volatility indicates dampening market efficiency. Our results confirm the nonlinear relation between volatility and price discovery and feature the dependence of market efficiency on the relative size of speculative trading. Our analyses so far focus on reportable trades only. To investigate the potential impact of non-reportable trades, we further analyze the relation between non-reportable trades and pricing efficiency. From unreported results, we find that the impact of non-reportable positions on pricing efficiency is significantly positive in the low trading position regime and it turns out to be negative in the high position regime, similar to those of speculators. The trading motive of non-reportable position holders seems to be speculative rather than hedging based. Röthig and Chiarella (2011) point out that non-reportable traders from the COT report are likely to be small speculators, who tend to follow large speculators’ trading strategies. Our results are thus consistent with Röthig and Chiarella (2011), which supports the idea that nonreportable traders are small speculators. The remainder of this article is organized as follows: Section 2 describes the data, including the weekly COT reports, FX futures from the CME, and spot exchange rates. Section 3 outlines our measure of price discovery through information shares and introduces the LSTR model. In Section 4, we present the empirical results before concluding in Section 5.