دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 18927
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

انتقال نوسانات در بازارهای آتی کشاورزی

عنوان انگلیسی
Volatility transmission in agricultural futures markets
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
18927 2014 6 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Economic Modelling, Volume 36, January 2014, Pages 541–546

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
کشاورزی - کالاها - بازارهای آتی - میانگین واریانس در گارچ - نوسانات -
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Agriculture, Commodities, Futures markets, GARCH-in-mean VAR, Volatility,
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  انتقال نوسانات در بازارهای آتی کشاورزی

چکیده انگلیسی

After the huge rise and fall of agricultural commodity spot and futures prices between 2007 and 2008, the potential reasons for and the impact of the strong rise in volatility provoked an intensive debate in the media as well as in the academic literature. However, owing to the increasing interdependence of global markets, an isolated examination of single futures markets does not seem to be appropriate. Therefore, the aim of this study is to investigate the volatility spillover between various agricultural futures markets from a new perspective. To do this, we use data for the prices of first nearby futures contracts for corn, cotton, and wheat and estimate GARCH-in-mean VAR models in the tradition of Elder (2003). Our results provide evidence in favor of an existing short-run volatility transmission process in agricultural futures markets.

مقدمه انگلیسی

Since agricultural commodity prices began to exhibit large swings between 2007 and 2008, the evolution of these has attracted considerable attention in the media and in academia. The FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations), which held a ministerial meeting on food price volatility on October 16, 2012 in Rome concerning this development, expects the increase in volatility to continue in the medium-term. This pattern does not appear solely in cash markets, but also in futures markets for agricultural products (Beckmann and Czudaj, forthcoming). To mention just one example, the price of the first nearby futures contract of soft red wheat traded at the Chicago Board of Trade (CBOT) increased by almost 200% from April 2007 to March 2008 and had decreased by 63% by December 2008 (see Fig. 1). Other agricultural commodity prices experienced a similar pattern. Thus, the role of futures markets is also discussed controversially when it comes to whether the potential engagement of speculative capital introduces volatility and price movements unrelated to demand and supply effects such as changes in the world population, economic growth or agricultural production (Piesse and Thirtle, 2009 and Wright, 2011). Generally speaking, futures markets can offer the possibility of gaining arbitrage revenues and thus exhibit speculation, while they may also form the mechanism by which new information is incorporated into prices if markets are efficient. These markets allow for the transfer of risk from commercial traders, who are exposed to futures price movements, to non-commercial traders, who are frequently labeled speculators and take short (long) futures positions in the hope of yielding a capital gain from the fall (rise) in prices.Against this background, this paper analyzes the futures markets of agricultural commodities from a new perspective. While previous studies have mostly examined either futures or spot markets separately or the link between them, we focus on spillover effects between various futures markets. The question of spillover effects is important for several reasons: firstly, general causality patterns can be identified. Secondly, co-movements of futures markets are a crucial issue for both investors and policymakers: on the one hand, the possibility of cross-market hedging can be affected. On the other hand, co-movements or cross-sectional volatility might be a result of a systematic influence stemming from a particular group of participants. However, it is worth mentioning that a direct evaluation of speculative pressure is beyond the scope of this study. As outlined further below, it is hard to judge whether speculation has the predominate role in increasing volatility. Nevertheless, it is important to shed some light on the general discussion regarding this issue in the following in order to put our findings in a general context. An implication of standard theory is that futures prices should follow a random walk with price innovations introducing new information and mostly uninformed traders or speculators trying to follow informed market participants. In this vein, a suggestive distinction between informed and uninformed traders is that informed traders will trigger a return to a fundamental value through trading if uninformed traders have previously moved a market away from its fundamental value (Gilbert, 2010a). With regard to agricultural markets, a related argument is that a limited number of traders, who previously supported investment and stabilized futures prices, were generally engaged before the group of futures investors or futures speculators, who regard agricultural futures as an asset, entered the market (Gilbert, 2010a). A popular line of reasoning is that these actors have no intention of selling in the real market, with their purchasing potential introducing volatility as well as upward or downward pressure or speculative bubbles on prices (Pace et al., 2008). In this context, Masters (2008), Masters and White (2008), and Gensler (2009) argue that extensive buy-side pressure from index funds has recently created a speculative bubble in commodity prices, with the consequence that prices heavily exceeded their fundamental values at the highest level.2 However, despite this popular line of reasoning, there is little clear-cut evidence that speculative trading affects the prices and volatility of commodities (Brunetti et al., 2011). The U.S. Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC) argues that the percentage level of speculation in agricultural commodity markets has remained relatively constant as prices have risen (CFTC, 2008). Testing the hypothesis of an impact from speculation provided by Masters (2008) and Masters and White (2008), Irwin et al. (2009), Irwin and Sanders, 2011 and Irwin and Sanders, 2012, Sanders and Irwin, 2010, Sanders and Irwin, 2011a and Sanders and Irwin, 2011b, and Bohl et al. (2013) also conclude that index investors have no impact on agricultural futures prices. On the other hand, futures price volatility should be positively influenced by the volume traded, according to various theoretical models which rely on traders with asymmetric information (Copeland, 1976 and Epps and Epps, 1976) or divergent beliefs (Harris and Raviv, 1993 and Shalen, 1993). Empirically, this pattern has been confirmed by previous studies which have found that increased trading volume is accompanied by increased futures price volatility, measured by absolute or squared returns (Chen and Lin, 2004, Ciner, 2002, Clark, 1973, Cornell, 1981, Kocagil and Shachmurove, 1998, Moosa and Silvapulle, 2000 and Wang and Yau, 2000). However, since futures trading in commodity markets is conducted by both hedgers and speculators, we cannot simply conclude which type of trader affects futures price volatility (Bohl et al., 2013). As mentioned above, we are interested in the role of volatility in agricultural futures, and one strand of the literature argues that a causal link exists between volatility and speculation. However, no enhancing influence of speculators is found by Brorsen and Irwin (1987) for six agricultural commodities and copper (1978–1984) or by Irwin and Yoshimaru (1999) for 23 agricultural, energy, and metal commodities (1988–1989). Both studies cover periods prior to the intensive financialization process of raw material markets. Focusing on the latter, the same result is obtained by Bryant et al. (2006) for three agricultural commodities, crude oil, and gold (1995–2003); Haigh et al. (2007) for crude oil and natural gas (2003–2004); and Brunetti et al. (2011) for corn, crude oil, and natural gas (2005–2009). By contrast, analyzing prices for corn, gold, and soybeans (1983–1990), Chang et al. (1997) detect that the positive effect of speculators' trading volume on volatility is much stronger than that of other traders. Finally, drawing on nine agricultural, energy, and metal commodities (1994), Irwin and Holt (2004) also conclude that speculative trading increases futures price volatility, but explain this relationship by valuable private information instead of noise trading. Cooke and Robles (2009) focus on international prices of corn, wheat, rice, and soybeans (2002–2009) and show that the observed change in food prices may be explained by financial activity in futures markets and different proxies for speculation.3 Detached from any reasoning about speculation, one sensible argument is that the complexity of agricultural futures markets has increased significantly for producers in recent times. In this vein, it is not surprising that an increasing number of empirical studies have put those markets under closer scrutiny. From a general perspective, analyzing the relationship between spot and futures prices for commodities to evaluate the price discovery role of futures markets, which may help reduce uncertainty, is a well-established research subject (Hernandez and Torero, 2010). It is often stated that, under the joint assumption of risk neutrality and rationality, the current futures price should be an unbiased estimator of the expected future spot price if changes in futures prices are uncorrelated with changes in other asset prices (Beckmann and Czudaj, 2013 and Beckmann and Czudaj, 2014). More related to our research topic, volatility spillover effects are about to become a popular line of research. In an early study, Buguk et al. (2003) examine the price volatility spillover in U.S. catfish markets based on monthly data running from 1980 to 2000. They conduct a univariate exponential generalized autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity (EGARCH) model and conclude that a strong volatility spillover from feeding material to catfish prices can be observed. More recently, Von Ledebur et al. (2009) analyze by means of a multivariate GARCH whether and to what extent the volatility of agricultural commodity prices at different market places were transferred during the dramatic price changes of 2008. They use a daily sample period from March 27, 2007 to March 5, 2008 and argue in favor of an operating volatility transmission. In this vein, the aim of the present study is to analyze the volatility spillover between different agricultural futures markets from a new perspective. In so doing, we use data for prices of first nearby futures contracts for corn, cotton, and wheat and estimate a GARCH-in-mean VAR model in the tradition of Elder (2003). Although we are not able to measure the influence of speculation directly, this may provide some insight into the issue if we follow the literature, which assumes a causality between speculation and volatility. For instance, recent studies by Cooke and Robles (2009) and Gilbert (2010b) indicate that the observed change in food prices may be explained by financial activity in futures markets and various proxies for speculation. Their findings are supported by Von Braun and Tadesse (2012), who argue that speculation effects are stronger than demand- and supply-side shocks for short-term price spikes. In this vein, our cross-market framework enables us to gain some new insights. Spillover effects across markets may arise as a result of common stochastic trends, which in turn might result from various fundamental or non-fundamental global factors. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. The following section describes our data, provides a description of and motivation for our empirical framework, and presents our findings. Section 3 concludes.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

Applying a GARCH-in-mean VAR model, we have shown that a volatility spillover can be observed in agricultural futures markets in the short-run. More precisely, we have demonstrated that the impact of the volatility of corn futures returns on the returns of cotton and wheat futures is statistically significant, but differs for both markets. This indicates that potential speculation effects on one market could be contagious for other markets and cause an increase in volatility in agricultural futures markets. Therefore, the recent rise in the interdependence of futures markets could be held responsible for the huge increase in volatility in agricultural prices in the last years. For this reason, it is not surprising that the increase in volatility of agricultural futures markets is expected to continue in the future. Through contagion effects, an increase of volatility in a specific market, which might be due to fundamental or non-speculative factors, is likely to transmit to other markets. In terms of policy implications, a reasonable conclusion might be that the frequently adopted macroprudential approach of supervising is superior to focusing on particular markets. However, the finding that volatility transmission is a short-run phenomenon leaves little room for direct ex-post policy actions. Considering that cross-market volatility may reflect market efficiency, it becomes even clearer that the task for policymakers is to analyze the origins of market volatility. Only some of the numerous possible reasons may then require political means. In this context, a distinction between positive and negative spillover effects is also important, since only positive volatility spillovers bear the risk of increasing volatility across markets. Finally, our paper offers an interesting starting point for further research. In particular, investigating different sources of volatility in agricultural futures markets might be an interesting research topic for the future. In particular, the frequently discussed link between the engagement of speculators and volatility remains on the research agenda.