دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 15385
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

آیا حق بیمه ریسک متغیر با زمان می تواند توضیحی بر عملکرد بازار کار باشد؟

عنوان انگلیسی
Do time-varying risk premiums explain labor market performance?
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
15385 2011 15 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Journal of Financial Economics, Volume 99, Issue 2, February 2011, Pages 385–399

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
حق بیمه ریسک متغیر با زمان - رشد حقوق و دستمزد - نرخ استخدام - جستجو و اصطکاک تطبیقی - بازار کار -
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Time-varying risk premiums, Payroll growth, Hiring rate, Search and matching frictions, Labor markets,
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  آیا حق بیمه ریسک متغیر با زمان می تواند توضیحی بر عملکرد بازار کار باشد؟

چکیده انگلیسی

Within the standard search and matching model, time-to-build implies that high aggregate risk premiums should forecast low employment growth in the short run but high employment growth in the long run. If there is also time-to-plan, high risk premiums should forecast low net hiring rates in the short run but high net hiring rates in the long run. Our evidence indicates two-quarter time-to-build in the aggregate payroll data, no time-to-plan in the aggregate hiring data, but two-quarter time-to-plan in the job creation data for manufacturing firms. High payroll growth and high net job creation rate in manufacturing also forecast low stock market excess returns at business cycle frequencies.

مقدمه انگلیسی

Modern asset pricing research has shown that aggregate stock market returns in excess of the short-term interest rate are predictable, meaning that expected aggregate risk premiums are time-varying.1 This body of evidence suggests that a large fraction of the variation in the cost of capital in standard labor market models is driven by time-varying risk premiums, as opposed to the interest rate. However, probably because of the long-standing divide between labor economics and finance (especially asset pricing), prior work that draws the linkage between time-varying risk premiums and labor market performance seems scarce. Our reading of the labor economics literature suggests that it has largely ignored the impact of time-varying risk premiums on the labor markets. In this article, we use the standard search and matching framework (e.g., Pissarides, 1985, Pissarides, 2000 and Mortensen and Pissarides, 1994) to study the impact of time-varying risk premiums on the labor market. When risk premiums are time-varying, different labor market frictions give rise to different sets of temporal relations between the expected return, labor hiring, and employment growth. Time-to-build means that hiring in the current period leads to more productive workers in the next period. Consider a discount rate drop at the beginning of the current period. The stock price rises immediately, meaning that the marginal benefit of hiring and therefore hiring also increase. With time-to-build, the employment stock increases only at the beginning of the next period. As such, the current-period employment growth is positive, and regressing it on the discount rate yields a negative slope. However, the discount rate drop also means that the realized return declines on average in the current period. The resulting lower stock price at the beginning of the next period means a lower marginal benefit of hiring and therefore lower hiring in the next period. Time-to-build implies that the next-period employment growth is negative, and that regressing it on the current-period discount rate yields a positive slope. In short, the discount rate should forecast employment growth with a negative slope in the short run but a positive slope in the long run. However, forecasting the next-period hiring rate with the current-period discount rate should yield only a positive slope without sign flipping at longer horizons. A similar logic shows that the effect of two-period time-to-build is to prolong the horizon over which the slope switches sign by one more period. Time-to-plan means that time lags exist between the decision to hire and the actual hiring expenditure. Consider again a discount rate drop but with one-period time-to-plan (along with one-period time-to-build). The discount rate drop at the beginning of t generates a higher stock price at t. With the planning lag, hiring rises only in period t+1 but remains constant in t. With one-period time-to-build, employment rises at the beginning of t+2 but remains unchanged in t+1. The discount rate drop also means that the stock return drops on average over period t. The resulting lower stock price at the beginning of t+1, together with time-to-plan, means a drop in hiring over period t+2 and a fall in employment at the beginning of t+3. Pulling the dynamics together, we observe that the discount rate should forecast employment growth (up to t+2) and the hiring rate (up to t+1) with a negative slope in the short run, but a positive slope in the long run. We report three empirical findings. First, measuring employment growth as the growth rate of seasonally adjusted total nonfarm payrolls from US Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS), we find that high values of the log consumption-to-wealth ratio (CAY) of Lettau and Ludvigson (2001) predict low payroll growth at short horizons within two quarters, but high payroll growth at longer horizons. Pulling all the information contained in standard risk premium proxies including the dividend yield, CAY, the relative Treasury bill rate, the term spread, and the default premium, we correlate the one-quarter-ahead fitted risk premiums with cumulative payroll growth over various horizons. We find that the correlations are insignificantly negative within two quarters, insignificantly positive at the fourth quarter, but significantly positive from the eight-quarter horizon and onward. The evidence so far suggests that either two-period time-to-build or the combined effect of one-period time-to-build and one-period time-to-plan is at work in the aggregate employment data. Second, we measure the hiring rate as the difference between gross hiring rate and separation rate from the Current Population Survey, conducted by the US Census Bureau for the BLS, and the BLS's Jobs Openings and Labor Turnover Survey (JOLTS). We find that high values of CAY predict high net hiring rates at various horizons. The correlations between the one-quarter-ahead fitted risk premiums with the I-quarter-ahead net hiring rates are all positive, ranging from 0.16 to 0.35, and are mostly significant. The evidence suggests that there is no time-to-plan in the aggregate hiring data and that the temporal relations between the discount rate and payroll growth must be driven by two-period time-to-build. The evidence is more supportive of time-to-plan in manufacturing firms. When forecasting the net job creation rate in manufacturing from Davis, Faberman, and Haltiwanger (2006), the relative bill rate has a significantly positive slope in the one-quarter horizon, a weakly positive slope in the two-quarter horizon, but significantly negative slopes at the four- and eight-quarter horizons. The correlations between the one-quarter-ahead fitted risk premiums and the I-quarter-ahead net job creation rates in manufacturing are significantly negative in the one-quarter horizon, effectively zero in the two-quarter horizon, and significantly positive in the four- and eight-quarter horizons. The evidence suggests that time-to-plan for hiring lasts for about two quarters in manufacturing. Third, lagged payroll growth predicts market excess returns, especially at business cycle frequencies. In univariate regressions, the adjusted R2 peaks at 5% in the four-quarter horizon. Across various horizons, the slopes are universally negative and mostly significant. Judged on Newey and West (1987)t-statistics and adjusted R2s in univariate regressions, the predictive power of payroll growth dominates that of standard risk premium proxies such as the default spread and the relative Treasury bill rate. Whereas the dividend yield and the term spread maximize their predictive power at long horizons, the predictive power of payroll growth peaks at short business cycle frequencies around four quarters. We also find similar evidence using the net job creation rate in manufacturing, but stock market predictability with the net hiring rate for the overall economy is weak. Our work shows that time-varying risk premiums are quantitatively important in forecasting employment growth. However, leading models in labor economics ignore risk premiums. In particular, the constant discount rate assumption is embedded in the partial equilibrium Mortensen and Pissarides search and matching framework. As such, risk premiums are constant and cannot forecast future employment growth. Merz (1995), Andolfatto (1996), and Gertler and Trigari (2009) integrate the search and matching model into the standard business cycle framework with general equilibrium. However, their models follow the real business cycle literature in assuming log utility, which in turn implies that the risk premiums in their models are close to zero and largely time-invariant. Our work is related to Lettau and Ludvigson (2002), who build on Barro (1990) and Lamont (2000) to study the impact of time-varying risk premiums on aggregate investment. We focus on the labor market. The asset pricing literature has only started to analyze the impact of labor on stock prices. Boyd, Hu, and Jagannathan (2005) show that stock market index responds positively to an announcement of rising unemployment in expansions but negatively in contractions. Merz and Yashiv (2007) quantify the importance of labor in explaining stock market valuation. Bazdresch, Belo, and Lin (2009) show that high employment growth predicts low average returns in the cross section. We instead study the impact of time-varying risk premiums on the labor market as well as stock market predictability with labor market variables. Finally, the voluminous literature on stock market predictability (see footnote 1) has largely ignored labor market variables. We fill this gap. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 develops testable hypotheses, Section 3 describes our data and test design, Section 4 presents the results, and Section 5 concludes.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

We show empirical linkages between the stock market and the labor market. We report three major findings. First, high aggregate risk premiums forecast low payroll growth within two quarters but high payroll growth in subsequent horizons. Second, high aggregate risk premiums forecast high net hiring rates for the overall economy from one to 16 quarters ahead. The evidence suggests that time-to-build, but not time-to-plan, is at work in the aggregate employment and hiring data. However, we also find that high aggregate risk premiums forecast low net job creation rates in manufacturing at the one-quarter horizon but high net job creation rates in the four- and eight-quarter horizons. The evidence suggests two-quarter time-to-plan in the manufacturing sector. Finally, we find that lagged payroll growth and net job creation rate in manufacturing predict market excess returns at business cycle frequencies, but that the net hiring rate for the overall economy does not. Our empirical analysis has implications for the existing labor economics literature. Most of the labor studies that build on the adjustment costs formulation of the labor demand (e.g., Hamermesh, 1996) or on the search and matching framework of Pissarides, 1985 and Pissarides, 2000 and Mortensen and Pissarides (1994) assume constant discount rates over the business cycles. However, the constant risk premiums cannot forecast future employment growth. Because of their log utility assumption, the general equilibrium models of Merz (1995), Andolfatto (1996), and Gertler and Trigari (2009) are likely to imply low and largely time-invariant risk premiums. As such, their models cannot explain our evidence on the linkages between time-varying risk premiums and labor market performance either. In all, our empirical analysis calls for a deep integration between labor economics and asset pricing.