دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 16567
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

برون سپاری مرزی و اصلاح حقوق مالکیت معنوی

عنوان انگلیسی
Offshoring and intellectual property rights reform
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
16567 2014 15 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Journal of Development Economics, Volume 108, May 2014, Pages 17–31

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
حقوق مالکیت معنوی - اختراعات - فن آوری - شرکت های چند ملیتی - برون سپاری - برون سپاری مرزی - انعقاد قرارداد دست دوم -
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Intellectual property rights, Patents, Technology, Multinational firms, Outsourcing, Offshoring, Subcontracting
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله   برون سپاری مرزی و اصلاح حقوق مالکیت معنوی

چکیده انگلیسی

This paper empirically assesses the responsiveness of US offshoring to intellectual property rights (IPR) reforms in 16 countries. We construct a measure of US offshoring at the industry level based on trade in intermediate goods, covering 23 industries for the period 1973–2006. For each industry, we differentiate between broad offshoring and intra-industry offshoring activities. We conduct a difference-in-difference analysis using the IPR reform years proposed in Branstetter et al. (2006, Quarterly Journal of Economics). We find that following IPR reform, neither broad nor intra-industry offshoring intensities change for the typical US industry at conventional levels of significance. However, high-tech (patent-sensitive) industries substantially expand their intra-industry offshoring activities, whereas low-tech (patent-insensitive) industries do not change their intra-industry offshoring activities in a statistically significant way. In addition, high-tech industries increase their broad offshoring relative to low-tech industries, but the effects are smaller and less robust than those estimated for intra-industry offshoring.

مقدمه انگلیسی

Over the past three decades, global trade policies and the composition of world trade have changed dramatically. Many developing countries (the South) started raising their intellectual property rights (IPRs) protection levels and building the necessary institutional framework. This transformation received an additional push in 1995 with the signing of the TRIPS agreement (Trade Related Aspects of IPRs) under the World Trade Organization umbrella, which called for establishing at least a minimum level of IPR protection by 2006.1 As the global movement towards stronger IPR protection picked up pace, the issue has generated intense debate among policy makers. The proponents of TRIPS have argued that such a move would reduce the imitation risk faced by Multinational Firms (MNFs) and would encourage more technology transfer and overseas activities. Moreover, it was emphasized that a stronger IPR regime would boost innovation incentives for all firms and thus accelerate global technological progress. Meanwhile, opponents have argued that TRIPS would simply lead to a transfer of rents from the South to the developed world (the North) and hinder the South's ability to implement newly-invented Northern technologies. Thus, the prospects of increased trade and MNF activity were the central motivations for the South to raise their IPR protection and further sign on to TRIPS. During the past three decades, North–South trade has indeed expanded dramatically. A central feature of this new era of globalization has been the rapid rise in intermediate goods trade, a phenomenon which is referred to as “offshoring”. More specifically, Northern producers fragmented their production processes into a variety of intermediate goods/services, sometimes referred to as tasks,2 and distributed them across the globe seeking the lowest-cost production locations. Production of intermediate products took place either within the boundaries of the MNFs (i.e., through foreign affiliates) or outside the boundaries (i.e., through arm's length subcontracting to Southern producers or through direct purchases from Southern manufacturers). A large literature has emerged, documenting and investigating the acceleration in trade and offshoring.3 Interestingly, only a few studies have empirically analyzed the effects of IPR regime changes on trade and MNF activities. For example, Maskus and Penubarti (1995) and Smith (1999) examine the relationship between IPR protection and trade using US data at the industry and state levels, respectively. Branstetter et al., 2006 and Branstetter et al., 2011 examine the link between IPRs and MNF activity by considering a variety of MNF measures (such as affiliate assets, affiliate R&D, affiliate overseas sales, intra-firm royalty payments and such).4 However, none of the papers in this literature examine the issue by using an offshoring measure based on intermediate goods trade. In this paper, our first goal is to construct a measure of US offshoring at the industry level that is mapped against the trading partners of the US and based on intermediate-goods trade. In doing so, we follow a methodology similar to the one used by Feenstra and Hanson, 1996 and Feenstra and Hanson, 1999. Specifically, we define broad offshoring intensity for an industry-country pair as the value of intermediate goods that a US industry imports from all industries of a given country to produce one dollar worth of output. Following the spirit of Feenstra and Hanson (1999, p. 24), we also consider intra-industry offshoring intensity (also known as narrow offshoring), which measures offshoring (again understood as imported intermediate inputs) that takes place within the same industry. To construct the offshoring measures, we use input–output coefficients and bilateral imports at the US industry level, covering the period 1973–2006. Our second goal is to empirically assess the responsiveness of US offshoring to IPR reforms in its trading partners. We identify the timing of IPR reforms in a total of 16 developing countries by following Branstetter et al. (2006). Our empirical strategy is to conduct a difference-in-difference analysis in the spirit of Branstetter et al., 2006 and Branstetter et al., 2011. More specifically, we regress our offshoring measures on a dummy variable which takes the value of zero before reform and one in the year of reform and thereafter, controlling for industry, time, and country effects, as well as country-specific linear time trends. We further extend the analysis by sorting the industries as high-tech (i.e., patent sensitive) and low-tech (i.e., patent insensitive) in order to account for patent-sensitive industries being possibly more inclined towards offshoring after IPR reform. We first run regressions without differentiating between industry types. These regressions imply that following IPR reform, neither broad offshoring nor intra-industry offshoring intensities change for the typical US industry at conventional levels of significance (5% or lower). We then run our regressions by distinguishing between high-tech and low-tech industries. These regressions uncover differential responses based on industry types. First, in the context of broad offshoring, we observe some evidence for increased offshoring by high-tech industries relative to low-tech industries. In particular, our baseline specification implies that high-tech industries increase their broad offshoring intensity by 31% relative to the insignificant 4% increase in low-tech industries. We should note though that the 31% estimate is only marginally significant (at 10% level) and becomes insignificant under some alternative specifications. Second, in the context of intra-industry offshoring, we now observe strong evidence for a differential response in relative terms. Our baseline specification implies that high-tech industries increase their intra-industry offshoring intensity by 128% relative to the insignificant 21.2% decrease in low-tech industries. In this case, the estimate of 128% is significant at conventional levels. Under alternative specifications, the estimates for the relative impact retain their significance albeit they lose some of their value. We also examine the changes in offshoring intensities in high-tech industries on their own (as opposed to focusing on the changes relative to low-tech industries). This simply involves testing the null hypotheses that the sum of the estimated effects reported above is equal to zero. We cannot reject the null hypothesis for the regressions with broad offshoring as the dependent variable at conventional levels of significance. However, we can reject the null hypothesis for the regressions with intra-industry offshoring as the dependent variable. Our baseline specification implies that high-tech industries increase their intra-industry offshoring by 79.6%. As a lower bound we obtain an estimate of 38.1%. We view these estimates as implying a sizable offshoring impact because intra-industry offshoring accounts for half of all offshoring by high-tech industries to our sample of 16 countries.5 In addition, we conduct an event-study analysis using the methodology of Jacobson et al. (1993). Our objective is to assess whether the timing of reform coincides with the timing of changes in offshoring and also address possible concerns about endogeneity of reform. To do this, we normalize the year of IPR reform to zero and regress our offshoring measure on a set of dummies for pre- and post-reform years. We find that prior to IPR reform neither broad offshoring nor intra-industry offshoring intensities show a statistically significant upward trend. We interpret this finding as alleviating concerns about endogeneity of reform with respect to offshoring. On the contrary, after IPR reform we observe that both broad and intra-industry offshoring intensities show an upward trend but with some lag, a reasonable result given that major institutional reform takes time to be fully enforced and implemented. In particular, the lagged effects are observed exclusively in high-tech industries. Following IPR reforms, broad offshoring intensities in high-tech industries increase relative to low-tech industries. The relative differential equals 15.3% at 2 years after reform, gradually increases with each year, and reaches 35.7% by 5 years after reform and thereafter. In terms of high-tech industry own effects (as opposed to effects relative to low-tech industries), we find that broad offshoring intensities in high-tech industries increase by 59.5% about 5 years after reform and thereafter. For intra-industry offshoring, we have similar results. Intra-industry offshoring intensities increase in high-tech industries relative to low-tech industries. The relative differential is 45.3% at 3 years after reform, increases gradually and reaches a differential of 124.3% by 5 years after reform and thereafter. With regard to own effects, we find that broad offshoring intensities increase in high-tech industries by 92.5% about 5 years after reform. All of the estimates reported above are statistically significant at conventional levels. In terms of magnitudes, these results are roughly in line with the difference-in-difference aforementioned estimators. To sum up, following IPR reform, we find strong evidence for increased intra-industry offshoring in high-tech industries and also some evidence for increased broad offshoring in these industries. In both the differences-in-differences specifications and the event study analysis, the intra-industry offshoring estimates are much larger and more robust than broad offshoring estimates. We should note that the event-study estimates provide stronger evidence for increased broad offshoring vis-à-vis the differences-in-differences estimates. Our paper differs from the empirical IPR-trade literature on a number of accounts. First, we construct a unique intermediate-goods-based measure of offshoring for each US industry disaggregated at the source country level. This differs from the existing literature noted above, which has used final goods trade, MNF related sales and payment levels. Second, our offshoring measure captures MNF activity, albeit at the industry level, that takes place both within and outside the boundaries of the firm. This differs from Branstetter et al., 2006 and Branstetter et al., 2011 and Bilir (forthcoming) who focus on intra-firm MNF activity measures and also from Javorcik (2004) who uses a binary Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) measure which equals one if a firm has invested in a country and zero otherwise. Third, we are able to distinguish between offshoring types in each industry as broad offshoring and intra-industry offshoring. Our utilization of a rich information set (input–output (IO) tables coupled with bilateral import data) enables us to construct these measures in a straightforward way. The existing literature does not have this type of distinction, neither at the firm nor at the industry level. We should note that our empirical findings are qualitatively in line with the literature, especially the recent ones, which find that IPR reform increases trade or MNF activities.6 Our paper is also related to a large body of theoretical literature that investigates the impact of increased Southern IPR protection on MNF activity, Northern innovation and Southern imitation. This literature can be classified into two categories: quality-ladders models where innovation (R&D) aims at improving the quality of existing products, and variety expansion models where innovation aims at developing new varieties of goods. The variety-expansion models find that IPR reform increases the rate of FDI [see, among others, Helpman (1993), Lai (1998), Branstetter and Saggi (2011) and Gustafsson and Segerstrom (2011)]. The quality-ladders models, on the other hand, offer mixed results. For example Glass and Saggi (2002) find that IPR reform decreases the rate of FDI, whereas Dinopoulos and Segerstrom (2010) have the opposite result.7 However, none of these papers explicitly considers fragmentation of production but instead assume full shifting of production to the South upon FDI success. In the quality ladders literature, two papers indeed stand out as highly relevant to our empirical framework. The first is Şener (2006) who extends the North–South quality-ladders model by incorporating fragmentation of production between the North and the South within each industry. In Şener's setting, MNFs offshore an endogenously chosen portion of their production to the South. Similar to Glass and Saggi (2002), Şener (2006) finds that stronger IPRs lower the rate of FDI. However, different results emerge with regard to the offshoring indicators. Southern IPR reform increases both the fraction of multinational industries and the portion of offshored production within each industry. This finding is also in line with Glass (2004), another relevant paper in the quality-ladders literature. In this paper, Glass constructs a North–South quality ladders model with exogenous offshoring and imitation rates. She finds that a more stringent IPR regime in the South raises the fraction of offshoring industries.8 In short, our empirical result that IPR reform leads to more intra-industry offshoring in paten-sensitive industries is in accord with the predictions of most of the recent theoretical work that uses a North–South growth and technology transfer framework. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes how the IPR reform dummy is constructed and explains how IPR reforms relate to technology transfer and offshoring. Section 3 describes the construction of our offshoring intensity measure and demonstrates some stylized changes in this measure by comparing the pre-reform and post-reform years. Section 4 presents our empirical specification, the data set, and the regression results. Section 5 discusses the issue of endogeneity regarding the timing of patent reforms. Section 6 concludes. Technical details of the construction of our offshoring measure, robustness checks, and variants of our empirical analysis are relegated to an online Appendix.

نتیجه گیری انگلیسی

Over the last three decades, world trade, and particularly, trade in intermediate goods and offshoring between North and South economies have increased dramatically. A large body of the economics literature has proposed several reasons for these trends in trade and offshoring (such as decreases in transportation costs, large improvements on ITC technologies, and growth in income levels). However, only a few studies have empirically investigated the impact of IPR regime changes on trade and multinational activities, and none of them have focused on the response of offshoring (which includes third-party contractual relationships in addition to within-multinational activities). Our paper empirically assesses the responsiveness of offshoring to Southern IPR reforms. In order to do so, we first construct a measure of US offshoring intensity at the industry level (for 23 manufacturing industries) mapped against the trading partners of US (16 economies). We construct two measures. The first, is broad offshoring intensity, which measures the value of intermediate goods that a US industry imports from all industries of a given country to produce one dollar worth of value. The second is intra-industry offshoring intensity, which considers the value of imported goods when US industry imports from the same industry abroad. Then, we employ a difference-in-difference approach and regress our offshoring intensity variables on a Reform dummy which identifies the timing of IPR reform for each country. In our specifications, we differentiate between high-tech industries and low-tech industries and control for several country, time and industry characteristics. We find that following IPR reform, a typical US industry offshoring to our sample of 16 countries does not increase its broad offshoring intensity or its intra-industry offshoring intensity at conventional significance levels. However, a differential response emerges when we distinguish between high-tech and low-tech industries. In particular, we find strong evidence for high-tech industries substantially increasing their intra-industry offshoring activities and some evidence for the same industries increasing broad offshoring activities following IPR reform. We did not find any statistically significant evidence for increased offshoring by low-tech industries. In both empirical approaches that we utilized, the difference-in-difference specifications and the event study analysis, we find that intra-industry offshoring effects for high-tech industries are much larger and more robust than broad offshoring effects. Further questions still remain to be explored in the context of IPR reform and offshoring. As noted in Section 2, our IPR reform dummy is a binary variable which obviously misses the possible heterogeneity across countries and also across industries. Future research can investigate this issue by coding up industry-specific patent laws across countries. Another natural follow up to our study can involve looking into the response of offshoring to IPR reform in countries other than the US. For many OECD countries, input–output tables and bilateral trade information exist to render such studies feasible.