دانلود مقاله ISI انگلیسی شماره 18130
ترجمه فارسی عنوان مقاله

مالکیت معنوی و تبعیض قیمت : آیا شما از عنوان نوآوری رضایت دارید؟

عنوان انگلیسی
Intellectual property and price discrimination: Do as you please in the name of innovation?
کد مقاله سال انتشار تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی
18130 2004 25 صفحه PDF
منبع

Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)

Journal : Information Economics and Policy, Volume 16, Issue 1, March 2004, Pages 31–55

ترجمه کلمات کلیدی
حقوق مالکیت معنوی - رقابت - نوآوری - تبعیض قیمت -
کلمات کلیدی انگلیسی
Intellectual property rights, Competition, Innovation, Price discrimination,
پیش نمایش مقاله
پیش نمایش مقاله  مالکیت معنوی و تبعیض قیمت : آیا شما از عنوان نوآوری رضایت دارید؟

چکیده انگلیسی

This paper considers policy towards the exercise of market power by holders of intellectual property rights (IPRs). In particular, we ask whether intellectual property protection should extend to price discrimination. To answer this question, we present a very simple model of IPRs, designed to make clear the trade-offs that face government policy makers in designing IPRs. We find that there are strong arguments for requiring price discrimination undertaken in the context of enforcing IPRs, that results, or is likely to result, in a substantial lessening of competition, to be subject to some form of public benefits test.

مقدمه انگلیسی

This paper considers policy towards the exercise of market power by holders of intellectual property rights. In particular, we ask whether intellectual property right protection should extend to price discrimination. Price discrimination is the sale of the same product to different consumers at different prices, where the differences do not reflect the cost of supply. In general, price discrimination is not directly attacked by competition law in Australia or New Zealand. However, the law in both countries prohibits agreements that have the purpose or effect of substantially lessening competition (unless there are countervailing benefits) and prevents firms from taking advantage of their market power for prohibited purposes: restricting the entry of others into the market, preventing others from engaging in competitive conduct, and eliminating others from the market. Hence, as a general policy, price discrimination which has the purpose or the effect of reducing competition would not be permitted. However, on both sides of the Tasman, the law exempts the above actions when they are carried out for the purpose of enforcing a statutory intellectual property right. This appears to grant to holders of intellectual property rights the ability to maintain exclusive, geographically or otherwise delineated distribution arrangements or to tie in the sale of other products in situations where such arrangements cannot necessarily be justified on the grounds of economic efficiency and without gaining authorisation. In this paper, we ask whether such exemptions are good policy. Our discussion is structured as follows. Firstly, we discuss price discrimination further and consider its consequences from an economic efficiency point of view. We then go on to consider the relationship between intellectual property protection and competition. Section 3 considers the welfare impact of intellectual property rights, with particular reference to the impact of changes in the design of intellectual property rights, and presents a simple model that identifies the trade-offs implicit in the design of intellectual property rights. We finish with a discussion of the implications for policy with respect to price discrimination in licences or contracts involving intellectual property rights. We conclude that licenses and contracts, arrangements or understandings involving statutory intellectual property rights should be subject to a public benefits test where they result, or are likely to result, in a substantial lessening of competition. We therefore agree in principle with the approach recommended by the Australian Intellectual Property and Competition Review Committee 1 with respect to section 53(1) of the Trade Practices Act, to the extent that it has this effect.