تحمل ریسک و قیمت گذاری خرده فروشی و سیاست های سفارش در چارچوب روزنامه فروش(تک دوره ای)
کد مقاله | سال انتشار | تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی |
---|---|---|
1891 | 2012 | 11 صفحه PDF |
Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)
Journal : Omega, Volume 40, Issue 2, April 2012, Pages 188–198
چکیده انگلیسی
This paper evaluates the pricing and ordering policies of a retailer, facing a price-dependent stochastic demand, within a newsvendor framework, under different degrees of risk tolerance and under a variety of optimizing objectives. These are (i) maximizing expected profit, for a retailer who may be risk-seeker, risk-averse or risk neutral; (ii) deriving a maximin strategy of maximizing a minimum guaranteed profit and (iii) modeling the probability of exceeding a target profit, as a constraint or as an objective. Some analytical properties and numerical examples illustrate the main features of the models and provide some comparative policy analysis across the model.
مقدمه انگلیسی
In the classical newsvendor problem (NVP), a risk-neutral firm facing a random demand decides the order quantity that maximizes its expected profit. The earlier NVP methodology assumes demand to be independent of price. Thus, the standard order-quantity results from the trade-off between the costs of under and over-stocking of units initially intended to meet the forecasted demand. The increasing importance of the tertiary over the secondary sectors of the economy worldwide and the lowering of product life cycles, as a result of the increasing importance of time-based competition, has substantially enhanced the incidence of single-period problems where the decision maker has to order ahead to satisfy an uncertain demand for an item/service that cannot be inventoried. Khouja [22] describes over 11 areas, ranging from multi-location problems to random yields, to different supplier pricing policies, where NVP formulations are of use. This depth and breadth of applications clearly attest to the saliency of the NVP in solving many strategic and tactical problems and to its flexibility to model cross-functional integration. Recent reviews of this topic appear in [8], [9], [22] and [31]. It should be pointed out from the outset that the term risk used in the current paper refers to the firm-specific or unique risk, as against the systematic risk, typically considered relevant in the finance literature. The underlying argument is that some of the risk may be eliminated if the returns from inventory investment are correlated with other investment returns. Hence, only the systematic or non-diversifiable risk needs to be considered for decision making. There are a few papers that have used the capital-asset-pricing model to characterize risk in a NVP (e.g. [4]). On the other hand, even if the systematic risk may be relevant for investors, because they have opportunity to diversify, a financial manager is rewarded by his/her own performance and, therefore, may not have the same opportunity to diversify. This explains, for example, the preference of unique risk reduction, as a motive for conglomerate mergers (e.g. [3]). Furthermore, managers who have to keep the interest of other stakeholders, like employees, have an ethical obligation to protect them against bankruptcy risk, a risk easily diversifiable for an investor [18]. In any event, for our paper, we focus on the unique risk, following the vast majority of the NVP literature. The purpose of this paper is to evaluate the pricing and ordering policies of a retailer who is facing a price-dependent stochastic demand, within a newsvendor framework, under different degrees of unique-risk tolerance and under a variety of optimizing objectives. Observe in the stated purpose the attempt to integrate three important streams of thought, being used, albeit separately, to adapt the NVP formulation to modern concerns. A brief explanation of these three topics follows. Early works on the subject (e.g. [23], [24] and [30]), considered cases, where the newsvendor is risk neutral and the selling price is constant and hence independent of demand and the objective to be optimized is the maximization of expected profit. Undoubtedly, a major shift in NVP modeling occurred upon recognition of the micro-economic principle of price-induced demand. Using the selling price as a decision variable provides the decision maker with an additional tool, with which to counteract the vagaries of demand uncertainty, in accordance to the standard tenets of micro-economic theory (e.g. [5]). This NVP does not restrict the retailer's decision process to simply placing an order at a fixed retail price. Instead, the retailer decides the price and order quantity that optimizes the expected profit. Recent reviews from this perspective appear in [9] and [31]. The other two underlying assumptions in most of the models in the literature are that the retailer is risk-neutral and that the desired objective is to maximize the expected profit. Schweitzer and Cachon [32], in their experimental study, where the buyers were deciding over quantity for a given price and demand distribution, observe that the retailer's behavior is not consistent with the traditional either risk neutrality or expected-profit maximization. In a more recent experimental study comparing Chinese and American ordering policy differences, Feng et al. [16] finds the former being more consistent to the more traditional behavior. These last two studies underscore the need to introduce the concept of degree of risk tolerance and alternate optimizing objectives in the NVP formulation. With respect to the degree of risk, Eeckhoudt et al. [14] and Agrawal and Seshadri [1] consider a risk-averse retailer who must choose the utility-maximizing price and quantity and compares the resulting policies to those of a risk-neutral retailer. However, in these models, the retailer has an opportunity to buy a second time, at a higher price, after realization of demand. This eliminates the risk of lost sales. Alternatively, Wang and Webster [36] study also the case of a risk-neutral manufacturer and a loss-averse retailer, without the second-purchase option, but with a buyback provision, that atones for the risk loss, while improving the profitability of both sides and of the chain as a whole. Chen et al. [10] considers also a risk-averse decision-maker, but within a multi-period framework. Ahmed et al. [2] drops the utility function criterion in favor of optimizing the worst-case expected profits or costs. In the process, this study shows that both the expected-utility and the worst-case approaches exhibit similar solution structures. Keren and Pliskin [21] use a linear utility function and a uniform demand distribution as a benchmark for more complex models. Wang and Webster [37] utilize a piece-wise linear utility function and shortage costs to illustrate how the retailer's ordering policy may increase (decrease) in wholesale (retailer) price, the higher the shortage costs are and the higher the degree of risk aversion. With respect to alternate objectives, the literature moved from the case of a risk-neutral retailer and price as a parameter and hence independent of demand. Current studies (e.g. [7], [24], [25], [26], [27], [29], [33], [36], [37], [38], [41], [42] and [43]) search for the attainment of satisficing or, its equivalent, maximizing the probability of achieving target-oriented objectives on one or various performance measures. For example, Lin and Kroll [26] maximize the expected profit subject to a minimum probability of exceeding a fixed target profit. Parlar and Weng [29] maximize the probability of exceeding an endogenous target profit, namely the expected profit. Recently, Yang et al. [42] consider the maximization of the probability of achieving profit and revenue targets simultaneously, whereas Shi and Chen [33] and [34] develop Pareto-optimal contracts under multiple objectives, be them satisficing [34] or not [33]. In addition, [11] and [17] evaluate risk-averse solutions under the conditional value at-risk minimization criterion, whereas the mean–variance criterion is the objective of choice to analyze the NVP for [12], [13], [27], [35], [39] and [40]. To integrate into the NVP formulation the three characteristics just described, this paper evaluates analytically the main features of four different models. All four include a price dependent demand, incorporate the retailer's risk tolerance in different ways and embed different optimizing objectives. Objective 1 considers the maximization of the risk-adjusted expected profit of a retailer who may be risk-seeker, risk-neutral, or risk-averse. Objective 2 deals with a maximin strategy that maximizes a minimum guaranteed profit. The other two extend the formulations of [26] and [29] to include degrees of risk and price as decision variables. Numerical examples throughout the paper illustrate the main features of the models and provide some comparative policy analysis across the models. They also discuss additional regularities, not characterized as properties, because the complexity of the underlying mathematical structures renders impossible their analytical justification. A Conclusions section completes the paper. Finally, throughout the paper, the arguments of the variables and the asterisks to denote optimality are omitted whenever possible, to simplify notation.
نتیجه گیری انگلیسی
The primary contribution of this paper consists of the integration of three streams of thought into the NVP formulation, namely a price dependent demand with price as a decision variable, an explicit recognition of the retailer's degree of risk as an integral part of the decision model and the inclusion of objectives other than the usual expected-profit maximization as alternate performance metrics for the retailer. This has given rise to a series of models that underline the relationships and trade-off between optimizing policies associated with risk-adjusted expected profit and the probability of exceeding a minimum target profit, be it fixed or moving, dependent or independent of the decision variables. A paper of this nature may be subject to a wide gamut of generalizations and extensions to adapt the underlying structure to a particular application. Examples include the type of demand distribution to fit alternate modes of demand error structure and the type of functional form of the deterministic portion of the demand to conform to alternate patterns, widely used, especially in the marketing literature. Additional modes of measuring risk along with extensive experimental analysis, such as that of [32], alluded to earlier, would go a long way to enhance our knowledge of the effect of the retailer's risk propensity on the pricing and ordering decisions. The study of these and other issues justifies additional research.