ممنوعیت اضافه بهای دریافتی در دستگاه های خودپرداز و ساختار بازار بانک: مورد آیووا و همسایگان آن
کد مقاله | سال انتشار | تعداد صفحات مقاله انگلیسی |
---|---|---|
19720 | 2007 | 22 صفحه PDF |
Publisher : Elsevier - Science Direct (الزویر - ساینس دایرکت)
Journal : Journal of Banking & Finance, Volume 31, Issue 4, April 2007, Pages 1061–1082
چکیده انگلیسی
It is frequently claimed that high ATM surcharges actually attract customers to the banks that impose them, particularly if they operate large ATM networks. By exploiting as “natural experiments” two events associated with the lifting of surcharge bans in Iowa and in the states that neighbor Iowa, this paper seeks to test for the implications of this phenomenon as it applies to the market shares of banking institutions and to several aspects of market structure. Consistent with predictions, results of “difference-in-difference” analyses suggest that the retail account shares of larger market participants increased relative to those of smaller competitors, market concentration increased, and the number of market competitors decreased after the lifting of surcharge bans – all relative to what would have occurred had there been no change in authority to surcharge.
مقدمه انگلیسی
When a depositor of one depository institution (hereafter “bank”) conducts a transaction using an ATM owned by another institution, the depositor may incur two fees: the so-called foreign fee, levied by the depositor’s own bank, and another fee, known as a surcharge, levied by the institution that owns the ATM. This latter fee has been the subject of some controversy. In popular commentary in the press and on Capitol Hill, it has been referred to as “double charging”, since it represents a second charge on the same transaction. A more substantive allegation, and one of perhaps more interest to the economist, is the claim that the ATM surcharge provides an example of a price that can actually attract customers to the firm charging a higher price. The reason is that surcharges typically are not levied for the use of a bank’s ATMs by the bank’s own depositors. Thus, a higher surcharge levied by a bank, particularly one that operates numerous ATMs, provides an incentive for depositors of banks with fewer ATMs to switch their accounts to the bank to avoid the fee. Thus, while a bank’s surcharge may discourage the depositors of other banks from using the bank’s ATMs (the “direct effect” of surcharging), it may actually encourage them to switch their accounts to the surcharging bank, and there is reason to believe that this “indirect effect”, as we will call it, is more pronounced, the larger the number of ATMs that the surcharging bank has to offer ATM users. The existence of this “indirect effect” has been central to discussions regarding the desirability of bans on surcharges. Some of this discussion has focused on the impact of surcharging on small banks, presumably because of a concern for the state of bank competition in the long run. Because of the indirect effect, surcharging may harm small banks either because it provides an incentive for depositors of small banks to switch their accounts to larger institutions with large networks of ATMs, or because it induces smaller banks to reduce retail fees or increase deposit interest rates to prevent, at least in part, the loss of deposits. As discussed in more detail below, a few recent contributions have sought to assess the broader welfare implications of surcharge bans, taking into account this indirect effect. This paper seeks to test for the existence of the indirect effect by examining the impact of surcharge bans on the market shares of banking institutions and on several aspects of market structure by exploiting as “natural experiments” two events associated with the lifting of a surcharge ban in Iowa and in the states that neighbor Iowa. The first of these events occurred on April 1, 1996, when the Cirrus and Plus national ATM networks modified their operating rules to allow ATM owners to impose surcharges. Surcharging thereafter spread steadily in the states that neighbor Iowa, but, because of state legislation, the ban remained firmly in force in Iowa. The second event occurred in March of 2002, when a court decision resulted in the lifting of the ban in Iowa as well. The statistical approach employed is that of a “difference-in-difference” analysis, wherein changes in bank-specific market shares (as well as related measures of market structure) occurring over a period in which a surcharge ban was lifted are compared to equivalently measured changes occurring over the same time period in neighboring states where no change in surcharge restrictions occurred. This approach, though simple, avoids some potential problems inherent in, and at the very least provides a useful alternative to, the more commonly employed structural econometric analyses appearing recently in the literature. Consistent with the presence of an “indirect effect”, results suggest that the retail account shares of larger market participants increase relative to those of smaller market competitors, market concentration increases, and the number of market competitors decreases after the lifting of surcharge bans – all relative to the case in which no change in surcharge restrictions occurs. The plan of the paper is as follows: Section 2 discusses the relevant literature, while Section 3 outlines the “difference-in-difference” analysis employed. Section 4 discusses the empirical model, and Section 5 describes the data and variable measurement. Section 6 presents results, and a final section concludes.
نتیجه گیری انگلیسی
The goal of this paper has been to test for the impact of ATM surcharging (inferred from information on ATM surcharge bans) on the market shares of financial institutions and on aspects of market structure. These tests exploit as “natural experiments” two events associated with the lifting of a surcharge ban in Iowa and in the states that neighbor Iowa. The first of these events occurred on April 1, 1996, when the Cirrus and Plus national ATM networks modified their operating rules to allow ATM owners to impose surcharges. Surcharging thereafter spread steadily in the states that neighbor Iowa, but, because of state legislation, the ban remained in force in Iowa. The second event occurred in March of 2002, when a court decision resulted in the lifting of the ban in Iowa as well. Employing a “difference-in-difference” methodology, the paper reports consistent evidence that the effective lifting of surcharge bans in states neighboring Iowa in 1996 caused (1) an increase in the market shares of the largest competitors relative to those of smaller ones (when market shares are measured as the share of accounts with less the $100 thousand in deposits), (2) a reduction in the number of competitors in the market, and (3) an increase in the Herfindahl–Hirschman index of concentration (when market shares used in its construction are measured as the share of accounts with less the $100 thousand in deposits) – all relative to the changes observed to occur in Iowa over the same time periods. Most differences were found to increase in magnitude over several years after the lifting of the bans. Results associated with the lifting of the surcharge ban in Iowa in 2002 tend to be weaker, perhaps because, as found for the 1996 event, the full impact of the lifting of a ban can take several years to observe, and data for only two years after the 2002 event are available. Nonetheless, they generally suggest that the same changes were at work in Iowa, after the lifting of its ban in 2002, as observed in neighboring states after the effective lifting of their surcharge bans in 1996. This is most clearly evident in the case of market concentration. When measured using the shares of market accounts with less than $100 thousand in deposits, concentration increased significantly in Iowa (relative to changes observed for neighboring states) after the lifting of its ban, just as it had in neighboring states (relative to changes observed in Iowa) after the lifting of their bans in 1996. These results provide fairly strong and consistent evidence of the much discussed “indirect effect” of surcharging, whereby the imposition of a surcharge (particularly by substantial market competitors with large ATM networks) actually attracts depositors to the bank, since this underlying relationship predicts all of the reported findings. A clear limitation of this analysis is that it does not allow us to assess the full welfare implications of surcharging. Among other changes, legalization of surcharging may provide greater incentive for financial institutions to invest in extensive ATM networks, providing greater convenience for their depositors. These results do demonstrate, however, (in a manner not dependent on the long list of detailed assumptions common to more structural approaches) that changes in market structure result from a change in the legal status of surcharging, and these changes appear to be economically meaningful.